Significantly,
the past two decades in Latin America have also been a period of "deindustrialisation",
as declining shares of investment and manufacturing valued added in GDP as
well as manufacturing employment in total employment have been coterminous
with stagnant or falling share of manufactures in total exports. This was
the same period in which the much more interventionist policy regimes in
East Asia were contributing to a significant expansion in manufacturing
activity from that part of the world.
The difference is clearly apparent in Chart 4. The share of manufacturing
in gross domestic product in
Asia has been rising, and is currently well above 30 per cent. By contrast,
Latin America
experienced fairly continuous declines in this share, and by 2000 this
share had fallen been below that in advanced industrial countries. The
point is that the process of deindustrialisation, or reduction in
manufacturing shares in GDP and employment, began in
Latin America at much lower levels of per capita income than the
equivalent and earlier process in the now developed countries. Chart 5
shows how the process has been rapid in the recent decade for at least the
three largest countries in the region.
Chart 4 >>
Chart 5 >>
In Chart 6 the
employment share of manufacturing is described, with developed countries
experiencing a clear decline and
Asia exhibiting an increase. In
Latin America, the
share of manufacturing in total employment rose (although less
significantly than in Asia) until 1990, and then declined to less than 15
per cent of the workforce on average.
Chart 6 >>
Nor did the neoliberal strategy operate to improve aggregate labour
productivity in these economies. In most countries of
Latin America,
overall productivity in manufacturing actually declined or remained
stagnant during the 1990s. In some enclave sectors where labour
productivity increased, this was essentially due to the shedding of labour
adding to unemployment, rather than greater investment and employment
expansion.
Chart 7 brings out the contrast between
Latin America and
Asia in this respect. The four Asian countries depicted there –
China,
Malaysia, South Koreas and Taiwan China – all indicate very rapid and
continuous increases in labour productivity in manufacturing over the
period 1985-2000. However, the four Latin American economies do not show
this positive tendency. Remarkably, manufacturing labour productivity
declined quite substantially in Argentina, was volatile and fluctuating in
Chile and Mexico, and only seems to have increased, albeit at a gentle
pace, in Brazil.
Chart 7 >>
Of course, at one level this is simply a comment on the difficulties
associated with measuring and capturing changes in productivity. Too
often, the data which actually reflect changes in the state of demand and
capacity utilisation are interpreted to denote changes in productivity
(which in turn reflects technological change). The falling productivity
indicators in Argentina, for example, reflect the worsening macroeconomic
situation over the decade, when output was stagnant or falling because of
restrictive macroeconomic and exchange rate policies.
It is also the case that a more disaggregated analysis reveals that there
are wide differences across sectors even within aggregate manufacturing in
these countries. From Chart 8 it emerges that the sharpest falls in labour
productivity in
Argentina
have been in food, textiles and electrical machinery sectors, while for
transport machinery the situation may have improved recently.
Chart 8 >>
In Brazil (Chart 9) transport machinery has witnessed large improvements
in labour productivity (which conversely can be interpreted as greater
labour shedding in that sector consequent upon newer more capital
intensive technology). Productivity also appears to have improved
marginally in food products and electrical machinery, and worsened in the
traditional manufacturing export areas of textiles and clothing.
Chart 9 >>
In Chile (Chart 10) in most sectors labour productivity improved by 2000,
although the pattern has been one of fluctuation and may be confused by
the end year results. In Mexico (Chart 11) as in Brazil, labour
productivity has increased mainly in the transport machinery and
electrical machinery sectors, and has declined for other manufacturing
sectors.
Chart 10 >>
Chart 11 >>
The overall picture seems to be that the weak investment performance in
the region tended to stunt productivity growth and upgradation. As a
result, international competitiveness has been increasingly based on low
wages (which is always an ephemeral advantage at best) rather than on
increases in labour productivity.
This has created peculiar results in terms of the behaviour of unit labour
costs relative to the
US,
which provide some basic idea of the competitiveness of particular sectors
in different countries. Table 1 shows the change in unit labour costs by
sector for the four major Latin American countries and four Asian
countries. It is evident that for the Latin American economies, unit
labour costs relative to those of the US have actually been rising in the
period 1980 to 2000, in most sectors. (Of course, this also depends upon
exchange rate policies and other such factors, rather than labour
productivity alone.) In consequence, unit labour costs were much higher in
Argentina (sometimes nearly double or more than double) compared to the
US. Even in the other countries, the gap between unit labour costs between
these countries and the US was been rapidly narrowed, which meant that the
advantage of cheaper labour may not be available for much longer.
In this context, even the opening up to more foreign direct investment has
not been entirely advantageous. A significant part of the FDI inflows into
the region have been in the form of acquisition of existing assets, often
in non-tradeable infrastructure or service sectors, rather than in
greenfield investment in new projects. Even the greenfield FDI has in
general been concentrated in sectors producing or processing natural
resources, rather than areas with high potential for productivity growth.
Meanwhile aggregate employment in productive sectors has suffered because
of more capital intensity in resource based industries, accompanied by
relative declines in traditional labour-intensive sectors such as textiles
and clothing.
Essentially therefore, the neoliberal strategy has mainly been successful
only in the very limited aim of inflation control. But this has been
achieved at the cost of a much worse record in terms of growth,
employment, poverty reduction, and higher volatility. The important point
is that the strategy failed not only in terms of social and distributive
consequences, but in terms of a much worse performance in investment,
growth and productivity. Not only has the transformation of the productive
structure through higher investment and technological change failed to
materialise, but many of these variables have actually deteriorated in
most of the economies of the region.