Despite the relatively
poor growth record of the era of corporate globalisation, there are many
who continue to believe that corporate globalisation and greater
liberalisation of economic policies do deliver higher investment and more
economic growth, even if there are other less benign effects - such as
greater inequality or inadequate "social sector" expenditure – which then
need to be separately addressed.
But in fact there is little evidence to indicate that the elements of the
neoliberal economic policy model actually work to deliver faster economic
growth. A good example of this – in fact, almost a laboratory test case –
is the region of Latin America, in which the majority of national
governments have been implementing this particular economic model with
some force, since the early 1980s.
The latest annual report from UNCTAD, the
Trade and Development
Report 2003,
contains a detailed discussion of the Latin American experience with
marketist reforms, and the effects on investment, growth, productivity and
employment. The results are quite damning for the neoliberal paradigm, and
call for a major rethinking of the entire strategy of development which
has been so comprehensively adopted on that continent.
In the 1960s and early 1970s, East Asia and Latin America grew at
approximately the same rate, and the five largest countries in Latin
America had per capita incomes that were above those of the first tier
NICS (Newly Industrialising Countries – South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore and
Hong Kong). Subsequently the pattern has been very different.
In the 1970s the large Latin American economies grew rapidly on the basis
of high accumulation rates financed by external borrowing, a process which
culminated in the debt crisis of 1982. Thereafter, there has not only been
slower growth but much greater volatility of economic activity in the
region.
From the point of view of policy orientation, the debt crisis of the early
1980s brought in a prolonged phase of very extensive market-based reforms,
which were urged on and supported by, and usually even enforced by, the
international financial institutions. Across the region, there were
sweeping changes in trade and industrial policy aimed at removing
protection to domestic producers and reducing what were seen as price
distortions.
There were reductions in rates of public investment, and continuous and
comprehensive privatisation of major state assets, in the major economies
of the region. There were cuts in explicit and implicit subsidies to
domestic producers and consumers, which also reduced the access of poorer
groups to public goods and services. There were attempts to reduce the
power of organised labour, through a combination of legislation and the
pressure of greater unemployment, in order to make labour markets more
"flexible".
These changes in economic strategy actually went further, and were more
comprehensive, than in any other region of the developing world. In most
of the economies, the change from the earlier import-substituting
industrialisation strategy became most pronounced in the aftermath of the
debt crisis of the early 1980s, although there were some beginnings in the
1970s.
In Chile, the shift to the neoliberal policy paradigm started much
earlier, with the Pinochet dictatorship of the early 1970s, and the
subsequent decades in Chile actually witnessed a slight modification of
that very extreme form of marketist approach, with greater role for
government intervention. Chile is an outlier in the Latin American case in
some important ways, but certainly shares some of the more significant
structural characteristics with other large economies of the region.
The explicit aim of the neoliberal policy package was, in the first
instance, to stabilise the economies by controlling inflation and reducing
macroeconomic imbalances. But the more significant medium term purpose was
to remove the constraints to growth, increase productive capacity and
external trade performance, and therefore reduce both the periodic balance
of payments crises and boom-bust cycles of growth. However, the experience
suggests that none of these aims has been even partially achieved in most
countries of the region.
Chart 1 provides evidence of growth rates in the 1990s in the major
regions of the developing world. Latina American growth is seen to be
definitely less rapid than that of Asia, although superior to that in
Africa. However, bear in mind that these average rates of growth in
Latin America came after the "lost decade" of the 1980s, which
experienced very sharp falls in per capita incomes and in wage incomes in
particular. In other words, the growth was from a relatively low base of
economic stagnation or decline in the earlier period.
Chart 1 >>
Chart 2
indicates the situation in the more recent period for the four largest
economies, Argentina,
Brazil, Chile and Mexico. It is clear that even in the latest period,
growth has been generally low and highly volatile, even in the so-called
"success stories" such as Chile.
Chart 2 >>
At one level the lower rates of growth in the Latin American region are
not surprising, because the region also experienced a fairly substantial
drop in investment rates (as share of GDP), among the highest in the
developing world. Chart 3 indicates that the comparison with
Asia can be instructive in this regard: not only have
investment rates in
Asia been high, but they have been increasing continuously over the long
period from the 1970s to now.
Chart 3 >>
In Latin
America, by contrast, there is clear evidence of a trend decline in
investment rates, from an average of 25 per cent in the 1970s to only
around 20 per cent or less in the recent past. The decline has been most
marked in Argentina, but even countries like Mexico which are supposed to
have benefited from the effects of closer trade integration with the US
through NAFTA, have shown low investment rates. Only Chile (where, as we
have already argued, the transition to the neoliberal economic regime
occurred already in the early 1970s) have investment rates increased over
this period, after initially falling.
This trend of declining investment rates was of course contrary to the
neoliberal expectation, that the removal of domestic prices distortions
and the freeing of market forces would improve the investment climate and
generate rapid increases in private investment. What happened in reality
was that there was a continuous decline in public investment, which in
turn meant that there were less virtuous linkage effects to encourage more
private investment, and so total investment rates declined.
In most countries in the region, aggregate investment rates in the 1990s
and after have fallen below the threshold level of 20 per cent of GDP. The
Trade and Development Report 2003
also argues that there has also been a broad
tendency for a shift in the composition of investment towards less
productive activities such as residential house construction, and away
from investment in machinery and equipment, in many countries of the
region.