The recent signs of buoyancy are all the more remarkable because they
occur at a time when world economic growth is slow. Given the role of
supply-demand balances in determining the level of agricultural commodity
prices, the latter are known to be extremely sensitive to the business
cycle in the developed countries, rising in periods of boom and falling
during the downturn. With the IMF admitting that optimistic projections of
a sharp recovery in world economic growth during 2002 are not likely to be
realized, there seems to be no stimulus from the business cycle for world
prices of agricultural commodities.
It is widely accepted that the reason why agricultural commodity prices
did not respond favourably to the 'implementation' of the Uruguay Round
Agreement, is that domestic support and trade protection for agricultural
producers in the US and EU remained high, resulting in high levels of
production and large . OECD figures indicate that in 2001, transfers to
farmers amounted to more than $300 billion, which was equivalent to 31 per
cent of total farm income and 1.3 per cent of GDP. Overall, the volume of
support has by no means fallen since the beginning of the implementation
of the AoA, athough relative to farm income, support levels fell from 38
per cent in 1986–88 to 31 per cent in 1999–2001.
Many factors combined to contribute to this situation. First, with import
tariffs and export subsidies having been raised substantially by developed
country governments between 1980 and 1986, the reference level of tariffs
and subsidies relating to 1986–88 which provided the base for the
prescribed reduction in protection and support, was so high that the
actual reduction in protection and support did not involve much by way of
the freeing of trade. In the run up to the reference years 1986–88, the
developed countries massively hiked their support to agriculture in
different forms so that their so-called 'reduction commitment' was
virtually meaningless. The USA raised its Producer Subsidy Equivalent,
which is only part of its total transfers to farmers, from 9 per cent of
the value of agricultural production in 1980 to as much as 45 per cent by
1986, namely, a 500 per cent rise in the relative share alone, and a much
higher rise in the absolute sums involved. It was this highly inflated
transfer that then became the base for reduction, so that after reduction
the transfers still remain a multiple of what they were in 1980. Second,
the shift away from amber box subsidies to green and blue box subsidies,
which were conveniently defined as non-trade distorting and non-violative
of WTO norms, resulted in the aggregate support to agriculture in the OECD
countries rising over time.
The impact of such support and protection is felt in various ways. First,
by raising the prices paid by consumers in the OECD countries themselves,
through tariffs and subsidies, they hold back consumption of agricultural
commodities. Second, by protecting farmers' incomes, they encourage larger
production than would have otherwise been the case, resulting in more
supply and larger exports that tend to depress international prices.
It is not surprising, therefore, that world production of many
agricultural commodities did not decline as expected. As Table 1
indicates, in the case of many commodities, world production increased
continuously since 1994–95, while in a few production increased initially
only to decline during the closing years of the 1990s. What is more, the
developed countries, which accounted for 85 cent of world trade in
foodgrains when the implementation of the Uruguay Round Agreement began,
have remained important producers and suppliers of these commodities to
the world market.
As against this supply-side scenario, world demand has tended to be
depressed because of the adoption of deflationary policies in most
countries, and because of the contraction of economic activity in many
countries in the wake of the financial crises that afflicted them.
Needless to say, this deflationary tendency has worsened in more recent
times, when growth in the only countries that had registered some degree
of buoyancy during the second half of the 1990s, viz. the US and the UK,
has also tended to decline.
Persisting high supply combined with depressed demand conditions imply
that in the case of agricultural commodities, where demand and supply
factors still have a role in influencing market prices (even if not
farmers' incomes), prices can be expected to decline. And this is
precisely what happened in the years starting around the mid-1990s,
resulting in the promise held out by advocates of the UR Agreement—that it
would result in a rise in world prices of agricultural commodities, a
decline in developed country exports of such commodities and a rise in
developing country export volumes—remaining unrealized.