Recent
evidence suggests of a new trend in the world prices of agricultural
commodities. The price of US maize, which ruled at close to $85 a ton in
April 2002, rose by 35 per cent, to $115, by September. The price of
soybean jumped from $172 a ton in February to $220 by September, a rise of
28 per cent in seven months. US hard red winter wheat climbed from $123 a
ton in May to $190 (a 54 per cent rise), while the soft red variety moved
from $111 to $154 (a 39 per cent rise). Other commodities, like palm oil,
coconut oil, cotton and cocoa, also recorded similar price increases
(Charts 1 to 8). The instances of stagnation or decline in the prices of
some commodities such as rice, groundnut and coffee (Charts 9 to 12),
appear to be exceptions rather than defining the rule.
These observed increases of between 25 and 55 per cent in the prices of
agricultural commodities within a relatively short period of time are
remarkable because they point to a new tendency in world commodity
markets. Till recently, most agricultural commodities had been
experiencing long-run declines in their prices, starting from as far back
as 1994 (Charts 13 to 16), which was the year when the Agreement on
Agriculture (AoA), signed as part of the Uruguay Round of trade
negotiations, began to be implemented. Advocates of the AoA had at that
time argued that its implementation would result in a decline in developed
country exports of agricultural commodities, and in an increase in the
volume and prices paid for agricultural exports from developing countries.
This was to result in substantial welfare gains for the developing
countries. In practice, however, those promises remained unrealized as
commodity prices underwent a long-run decline. But if the new tendency for
prices to rise is sustained over the coming months, we could be witnessing
a major breakthrough for commodity producers in world markets.
While it is true that primary products as a whole accounted for just 30
per cent of developing country exports at the end of the 1990s as compared
to more than 90 per cent in the mid-1950s, and that the share of non-fuel
primary products (agricultural products and non-ferrous metals) in
developing country exports fell by nearly one half, to 12 per cent,
between the mid-1980s and late 1990s, agricultural exports are still
important to a large number of countries. According to figures collated by
the WTO, in the late 1960s, the large majority of developing countries,
103 out of 111 to be precise, were predominantly exporters of primary
products. Between 1968–70 and 1998–2000, only 27 of these made the
transition to being predominantly exporters of manufactured products and
76 remained primary product exporters, with a large number of them being
dependent on agricultural exports. The prospect of buoyancy in
agricultural prices is therefore of some significance to poor countries,
especially in Africa.
The recent signs of buoyancy are all the more remarkable because they
occur at a time when world economic growth is slow. Given the role of
supply-demand balances in determining the level of agricultural commodity
prices, the latter are known to be extremely sensitive to the business
cycle in the developed countries, rising in periods of boom and falling
during the downturn. With the IMF admitting that optimistic projections of
a sharp recovery in world economic growth during 2002 are not likely to be
realized, there seems to be no stimulus from the business cycle for world
prices of agricultural commodities.
It is widely accepted that the reason why agricultural commodity prices
did not respond favourably to the 'implementation' of the Uruguay Round
Agreement, is that domestic support and trade protection for agricultural
producers in the US and EU remained high, resulting in high levels of
production and large . OECD figures indicate that in 2001, transfers to
farmers amounted to more than $300 billion, which was equivalent to 31 per
cent of total farm income and 1.3 per cent of GDP. Overall, the volume of
support has by no means fallen since the beginning of the implementation
of the AoA, athough relative to farm income, support levels fell from 38
per cent in 1986–88 to 31 per cent in 1999–2001.
Many factors combined to contribute to this situation. First, with import
tariffs and export subsidies having been raised substantially by developed
country governments between 1980 and 1986, the reference level of tariffs
and subsidies relating to 1986–88 which provided the base for the
prescribed reduction in protection and support, was so high that the
actual reduction in protection and support did not involve much by way of
the freeing of trade. In the run up to the reference years 1986–88, the
developed countries massively hiked their support to agriculture in
different forms so that their so-called 'reduction commitment' was
virtually meaningless. The USA raised its Producer Subsidy Equivalent,
which is only part of its total transfers to farmers, from 9 per cent of
the value of agricultural production in 1980 to as much as 45 per cent by
1986, namely, a 500 per cent rise in the relative share alone, and a much
higher rise in the absolute sums involved. It was this highly inflated
transfer that then became the base for reduction, so that after reduction
the transfers still remain a multiple of what they were in 1980. Second,
the shift away from amber box subsidies to green and blue box subsidies,
which were conveniently defined as non-trade distorting and non-violative
of WTO norms, resulted in the aggregate support to agriculture in the OECD
countries rising over time.
The impact of such support and protection is felt in various ways. First,
by raising the prices paid by consumers in the OECD countries themselves,
through tariffs and subsidies, they hold back consumption of agricultural
commodities. Second, by protecting farmers' incomes, they encourage larger
production than would have otherwise been the case, resulting in more
supply and larger exports that tend to depress international prices.
It is not surprising, therefore, that world production of many
agricultural commodities did not decline as expected. As Table 1
indicates, in the case of many commodities, world production increased
continuously since 1994–95, while in a few production increased initially
only to decline during the closing years of the 1990s. What is more, the
developed countries, which accounted for 85 cent of world trade in
foodgrains when the implementation of the Uruguay Round Agreement began,
have remained important producers and suppliers of these commodities to
the world market.
As against this supply-side scenario, world demand has tended to be
depressed because of the adoption of deflationary policies in most
countries, and because of the contraction of economic activity in many
countries in the wake of the financial crises that afflicted them.
Needless to say, this deflationary tendency has worsened in more recent
times, when growth in the only countries that had registered some degree
of buoyancy during the second half of the 1990s, viz. the US and the UK,
has also tended to decline.
Persisting high supply combined with depressed demand conditions imply
that in the case of agricultural commodities, where demand and supply
factors still have a role in influencing market prices (even if not
farmers' incomes), prices can be expected to decline. And this is
precisely what happened in the years starting around the mid-1990s,
resulting in the promise held out by advocates of the UR Agreement—that it
would result in a rise in world prices of agricultural commodities, a
decline in developed country exports of such commodities and a rise in
developing country export volumes—remaining unrealized.
This is what makes the recent rise in prices even more surprising. As the
US Farm Bill 2002 makes clear, developed countries are by no means
reducing the income support they provide to their farmers. World output
and trade are now even more depressed than was the case in 2001 or
earlier, implying that world demand for primary commodities would also be
depressed. And agricultural prices continue to be determined by demand and
supply factors. What, then, explains the recent buoyancy in prices?
Three factors, clearly, have a role to play in this. The first is the
lagged effect of low prices on production, since direct income support has
increasingly been decoupled from production decisions, even if not
completely. The second is the spurred demand for agricultural commodities
resulting from sharply reduced prices. The net result of this has been
that the volume of stocks of individual commodities has tended to either
stagnate or decline. This basic tendency has been worsened in the case of
those commodities for which country-specific developments, such as drought
or pest attacks, have reduced world supply even further. Such factors have
been important in recent times. For example, according to the IMF's
World Economic Outlook: 'Grain prices edged up during the first half
of 2002, largely due to adverse weather conditions in the United States,
Canada, and Australia and consequent declines in global stocks. In the
near term, however, further price increases are limited by increased
competition from other producers such as Argentina and Brazil, while the
European Union may reinstate export subsidies. Vegetable oils and meals
prices have shown a more pronounced recovery than other agricultural
commodities, largely reflecting a reversal of extremely depressed levels
in 2000–01. Palm and coconut oil prices have increased owing to small
crops in major producer countries and reduced inventories; palm oil prices
have also been affected by large purchases in India and Pakistan to guard
against possible supply disruptions stemming from political conflict.'
The role played by these supply and demand adjustments to low prices can
be seen from Table 1, which shows that in the case of many commodities,
both output and stocks have tended to decline over the last two years. The
basic reason for the paradoxical buoyancy of prices in a period of
depressed economic conditions is to be found in these adjustments. That
is, when low or high prices prevail for long enough, the cobweb-type
behaviour expected in textbook analyses does in fact play a role, leading
to the unusual price behaviour characteristic of recent months.
To these we need to add the influence of a third factor: the role of
speculative holding of commodities that tends to increase in periods when
stockmarkets are depressed. There is reason to believe that the collapse
of stock markets in the wake of the busting of the tech boom and the
revelations of accounting fraud aimed at boosting share prices have
resulted in a flight to safety which has found liquidity increasing in
commodity markets. Since this happened at a time when production and stock
adjustments were in any case tending to raise prices, the sharp rise in
the prices of some commodities may be the result of speculative
influences.
Equity markets in the developed industrial countries were in free fall,
with what the IMF describes as 'surprising synchronicity', between
end-March and late-July 2002. Some degree of volatility since then has not
helped investors recoup the huge losses they incurred in recent months.
Those losses were the inevitable outcome of the winding-down of markets,
once it became clear that earlier profit figures had been inflated to
satisfy investors, that profit projections were unduly optimistic, and
that the 'recovery' in the US during the first quarter of 2002 was not
going to last. According to the IMF: 'In the face of increased risk and
uncertainty, demand for government bonds and high-quality corporate paper
has risen, which—together with expectations that monetary tightening will
be postponed—has driven long-run interest rates down significantly.
Spreads for riskier borrowers have risen, and risk appetite has also
declined.' Moreover, investors are now increasingly worried that the
dollar, which has thus far defied all laws of economic gravity and ruled
high despite record trade and current account deficits in the US, may in
fact weaken, necessitating a shift out of dollar-denominated financial
assets. In this context, what has also perhaps occurred is a shift of
investors from financial to real assets, especially commodities, based on
preliminary indications that commodity markets will remain firm because of
lower production levels and lower stocks. This too could be driving up
commodity prices, even if in the short run.
The simultaneous operation of all these factors comprises a possible
explanation for the unusual buoyancy of commodity prices. But since none
of these factors implies any change in the fundamental determinants of
agricultural commodity prices, which still work to depress those prices in
the long run, the observed buoyancy will, in all probability, be
shortlived.