The
Asian region typically has the lowest rates of open unemployment in the
world, but even here, as can be seen from Table 1, these rates have been
historically high and rising, especially in Southeast Asia. This extensive
slack in labour markets across the world is a direct reflection of the
global recessionary tendency that has already been discussed above, and
all the evidence suggests that this slack has been increasing in recent
years, as economies even in the developing world continue to operate far
below potential. Furthermore, in most Asian countries, youth unemployment
is especially high.
In many Asian economies, moreover, underemployment continues to be a
significant concern. This is especially true in Southeast and South Asia.
In Nepal underemployment is officially estimated to be as high as half the
work force, while in Indonesia and the Philippines disguised unemployment
is high and rising, especially in the informal sector.
Another very significant change in the recent past is the decline in
formal-sector employment. Once again, this is a trend that is spread
across the globe and covers both developed and developing countries. In
developing countries, the substantial reduction in the share of
organized-sector employment has been associated not only with increased
open unemployment but also the proliferation of workers crowded into the
informal sector, and typically more in the low-wage, low-productivity
occupations that are characteristic of 'refuge sectors' in labour markets.
While there are also some high value-added jobs increasingly in the
informal sector (including, for example, computer professionals and some
high-end IT-enabled services), these are relatively small in number and
certainly too few to make much of a dent in the overall trend, especially
in countries where the vast bulk of the labour force is unskilled or
relatively less skilled. In turn, this has meant that the cycle of
poverty–low employment generation–poverty has been accentuated because of
the diminished willingness or ability of developing country governments to
intervene positively for expanded employment generation.
The decline in employment elasticities of production is a tendency that is
especially marked in developing countries. To some extent, this reflects
the impact of international concentration of production and export
orientation, as the necessity of making products that will be acceptable
in world markets requires the use of new technologies developed in the
North and inherently labour-saving in nature. But what is interesting is
the extent to which declining employment elasticities in developing Asia
have marked all major productive sectors, including agriculture. This is
evident from Table 2, which describes the employment elasticity of GDP
growth in the major productive sectors over 1990–2000 in the major
economies of Southeast and South Asia. Agriculture is clearly no longer a
refuge sector for those unable to find employment elsewhere-the data
indicate low or even negative employment elasticity in this sector,
reflecting a combination of labour-saving technological changes such as
greater use of threshers and harvesters, and changes in landholding
patterns resulting in lower extents of traditional small peasant farming
because of the reduced economic viability of smallholder cultivation
across the region. The service sector, by contrast, seems to have emerged
as the refuge sector in this region, except possibly in countries like Sri
Lanka and India.
Table 2 >>
The emergence of global production chains is another important feature of
the recent past. These are not entirely new, and even the current chains
can be dated from at least the 1980s. However, two major sets of changes
have dramatically increased the relocation possibilities in international
production. The first set includes technological changes, which have
allowed for different parts of the production process to be split and
locationally separated, as well as created different types of requirement
for labour involving a few highly skilled professional workers and a vast
bulk of semi-skilled workers for whom burn-out is more widely prevalent
than learning by doing. The second set includes organizational changes
which are associated with concentration of ownership and control, but also
with greater dispersion and more layers of outsourcing and subcontracting
of particular activities and parts of the production process.
Therefore, we now have the emergence of international suppliers of goods
who rely less and less on direct production within a specific location and
more on subcontracting a great part of their production activities. Thus
the recent period has seen the emergence and market domination of
'manufacturers without factories', as multinational firms such as Nike and
Adidas effectively rely on a complex system of outsourced and
subcontracted production based on centrally determined design and quality
control. This has been strongly associated with an increase in
export-oriented production in manufacturing in a range of developing
countries, especially in textiles and garments, computer hardware,
consumer electronics and related sectors. It is true that the increasing
use of outsourcing is not confined to export firms; however, because of
the flexibility offered by subcontracting, it is clearly of greater
advantage in the intensely competitive exporting sectors and therefore
tends to be more widely used there.
Much of this outsourcing activity is based in Asia, although Latin America
is emerging as an important location once again. Such subcontracted
producers vary in size and manufacturing capacity, from medium-sized
factories to pure middlemen collecting the output of home-based workers.
The crucial role of women workers in such international production
activity is now increasingly recognized, whether as wage labour in small
factories and workshops run by subcontracting firms, or as piece-rate
payment-based home workers who deal with middlemen in a complex production
chain.
Finally, there is the very significant effect of international migration,
in determining changes in both national labour markets and macroeconomic
processes within home and host countries. In Latin America, migration is a
response to the lack of productive employment opportunities within the
country-at least 15 per cent of the labour force of most Central American
countries (in particular, El Salvador, Guatemala and the Honduras) is
estimated to be working in the United States, mostly in underpaid,
oppressive and precarious jobs. Migration flows are especially marked for
Asia over the last two decades, and within the broad Asian region. South
Asian migrant workers in the Gulf and West Asia have contributed huge
flows of remittance income which has stabilised the current account in
India and Bangladesh, for example. Within Southeast Asia, Thailand is host
to approximately 890,000 migrant workers, while Malaysia is estimated to
have more than 900,000 on official count. In Singapore, one quarter of the
work force is comprised of migrants. Typically, of course, such migrants
are used for 3-D jobs ('difficult, dirty and dangerous') as well as in
unskilled sectors. In Malaysia, for example, 70 per cent of the unskilled
construction workers come from Indonesia. What is noteworthy about Asian
migration is the significant role played by women migrants, especially
from the Philippines but also from other parts of the continent. It should
be noted, of course, that the line between voluntary migration and
trafficking is often quite thin.
Emerging
Processes
There are a number of important processes
currently at work, which will shape national, regional and international
labour markets in the near future. The first is a process that is still
unfolding, and is likely to have possibly seismic effects on patterns of
work across the world-the demographic shifts and consequent
imbalances in population structure as between industrial and developing
countries.
The ageing population structure of most industrial societies, and even
some developing countries in the western hemisphere, implies that by the
next decade of this century, many activities will effectively have to be
outsourced to other regions, whether through labour migration or through
devices made possible by new technology, such as IT-enabled services. By
2010, it is estimated that nearly 60 per cent of the world's labour force
will be in Asia, which still has a dominantly young population. This is
surely likely to have profound implications for patterns of development
and for labour markets, which are still inadequately comprehended.
The current crisis in developing country agriculture and the growing
problems of even subsistence farming are also likely to have major
implications, not only for the present, with agrarian crisis becoming a
standard feature of most developing economies, but also for the future. It
is in this context that the overall inadequacies of employment generation
in other sectors become even more problematic. The breakdown of
traditional Lewis-type mechanisms of moving labour from agriculture to
other more dynamic sectors, in a context in which global integration of
distorted agricultural markets is making even traditional subsistence
cultivation difficult if not unviable, is likely to make employment the
single most important social issue in almost all developing societies in
the near future.
Two other issues,
which have recently attracted a lot of discussion, deserve to be
considered in more detail. The
first
relates to
the perception widespread in the North, that manufacturing jobs are being
exported from North to South. The
second is the
issue of feminization of work,
especially export-oriented work, in the developing world.
The last
decade has seen a significant shift in the structure of international
manufacturing production, such that developing countries now account for
nearly a quarter of the world's manufacturing goods exports, up from just
over one-tenth two decades ago. Such relocation, which in turn is supposed
to imply a net loss of manufacturing jobs in the North and a net expansion
of such jobs in the South, has been seen as being driven by both the
movement of capital, as multinational companies in particular move to
areas characterized by cheaper labour, and trade liberalization, which has
allowed manufactured goods produced in Southern locations to penetrate
Northern markets.
In actual fact, however, there is little evidence of the 'export' of
manufacturing jobs.The
vast majority of developing countries have experienced very substantial
losses in manufacturing employment as a result of the liberalization of
trade and financial markets. Even the top thirteen developing country
exporters (excluding China) do not show increases in manufacturing
employment. So, while such jobs may have declined in the North, they have
not increased commensurately in the South, even in the group of most
dynamic developing country exporters. This is because trade liberalization
has meant loss of many manufacturing jobs in developing countries to
imports even as some jobs may have increased through exports, and because
technological changes in both the North and the South have given rise to
low and declining employment elasticities of manufacturing production.
These factors in turn stem from a larger process of national and
international concentration of production, intensification of competitive
pressure and the greater power of large capital. These have accelerated
the adoption of labour-saving technology, encouraged flexible labour
market practices, adversely affected small manufacturing enterprises, and
induced a deflationary policy bias into most economies. All of these have
impacted adversely on employment, leading to the 'disappearance' of
manufacturing jobs, rather than their export.
Another common perception relates to the fact that the increasing
importance of export-oriented manufacturing activities in many developed
countries has been associated with a much greater reliance on women's paid
labour. This process was most marked over the period 1980 to 1995 in the
high-exporting economies of East and Southeast Asia, where the share of
female employment in total employment in the export processing zones (EPZs)
and export-oriented manufacturing industries typically exceeded 70 per
cent. It was also observed in a number of other developing countries, for
example in Latin America, in certain types of export manufacture.
Women workers were preferred by employers in export activities primarily
because of the inferior conditions of work and pay that they were usually
willing to accept. Women workers had lower reservation wages than their
male counterparts, were more willing to accept longer hours and
unpleasant, often unhealthy or hazardous, factory conditions, typically
did not unionize or engage in other forms of collective bargaining to
improve conditions, and did not ask for permanent contracts. They were
thus easier to hire and fire at will and according to external demand
conditions, and also, life-cycle changes such as marriage and childbirth
could be used as proximate causes to terminate employment. Another
important reason for feminization was the greater flexibility afforded by
such labour for employers, in terms of less secure contracts. Further, in
some of the newer 'sunrise' industries of the period, such as the computer
hardware and consumer electronics sectors, the nature of the assembly-line
work-repetitive and detailed, with an emphasis on manual dexterity and
fineness of elaboration-was felt to be especially suited to women. The
high 'burn-out' associated with some of these activities meant that
employers preferred work forces that could be periodically replaced, which
was easier when the employed group consisted of young women who could move
on to other phases of their life-cycle.
The feminization of such activities had both positive and negative effects
for the women concerned. On the one hand, it definitely meant greater
recognition and remuneration of women's work, and typically improved the
relative status and bargaining power of women within households, as well
as their own self-worth, thereby leading to empowerment. On the other
hand, it is also true that most women are rarely if ever 'unemployed' in
their lives, in that they are almost continuously involved in various
forms of productive or reproductive activities, even if they are not
recognized as 'working' or paid for such activities. This means that the
increase in paid employment may lead to an onerous double burden of work
unless other social policies and institutions emerge to deal with
the work traditionally assigned to (unpaid) women.
Given these features, it has been fairly clear for some time now that the
feminization of work need not be a cause for unqualified celebration on
the part of those interested in improving women's material status.
However, it is now becoming evident that the process of feminization of
labour in export-oriented industries may have been even more dependent
upon the relative inferiority of remuneration and working conditions than
was generally supposed. This becomes very clear from a consideration of
the pattern of female involvement in paid labour markets in East and
Southeast Asia, and more specifically in the export industries, over the
entire 1990s. What the evidence suggests is that the process of
feminization of export employment really peaked somewhere in the early
1990s (if not earlier in some countries), and that thereafter the process
was not only less marked but may even have begun to peter out. This is
significant because it refers very clearly to the period before the
effects of the financial crisis began to make themselves felt on real
economic activity, and even before the slowdown in the growth rate of
export production. So, while the crisis may have hastened the process
whereby women workers are disproportionately prone to job loss because of
the very nature of their employment contracts, in fact, the marginal
reliance on women workers in export manufacturing activity (or rather, in
the manufacturing sector in general) had already begun to reduce before
the
crisis.
A reversal of the process of feminization of work has already been
observed in other parts of the developing world, notably in Latin America.
Quite often, such declines in the female share of employment have been
found to be associated with either one of two conditions: an overall
decline in employment opportunities because of recession or structural
adjustment measures, or a shift in the nature of the new employment
generation towards more skilled or lucrative activities. There could be
another factor. As women became an established part of the paid work
force, and even the dominant part in certain sectors (as indeed they did
become in the textiles, readymade garments and consumer electronics
sectors of East Asia), it became more difficult to exercise the
traditional type of gender discrimination at work. Not only was there an
upward pressure on their wages but also other pressures for legislation
which would improve their overall conditions of work. Social action and
legislation designed to improve the conditions of women workers tended to
reduce the relative attractiveness of women workers for those employers
who had earlier relied on the inferior conditions of women's work to
enhance their export profitability. The rise in wages also tended to have
the same effect. Thus, as the relative effective remuneration of women
improved (in terms of the total package of wage and work and contract
conditions), their attractiveness to employers decreased.
Conclusion
The recent
trends and emerging processes described above point to some very difficult
issues for policy, even as employment generation is becoming the single
most pressing concern in most societies. Quite simply, the basic question
relates to how adequate and decent work is to be ensured for men and women
workers, in an international
context in which greater economic integration has drastically altered the
contours of public policy as well as the requirements of employers. It may
be that policies directed towards labour markets are less effective in
securing desired outcomes; rather, it may be necessary to shift and
reorient basic macroeconomic policies towards more growth and employment
generation in general.
[2]
This
argument is developed and substantiated in Ghosh
"Exporting jobs or watching them disappear?
Relocation, employment and accumulation in the
world economy",
in Ghosh and Chadrasekhar (eds) Work and well-being
in the age of finance, Tulika Books 2002.
[3]
This
argument is provided in more detail in Ghosh "Export-oriented
employment of women in India" in Razavi and Pearson
(eds) Social policy and women's export employment,
Macmillan, forthcoming.