|
|
|
|
A
Note on Fiscal Devolution and the Centrally Sponsored
Schemes |
|
May
26th 2008, Jayati Ghosh |
|
Under
the Constitution, State governments have always had
very significant responsibilities (for law and order,
infrastructure development, health, education, agriculture
– to name just a few). However, at the same time they
have not had commensurate powers either to raise resources
or to influence broader trends that create the context
or enabling condi"tions for fulfilling these responsibilities.
This is why the fundamental fiscal difference between
Centre and States – that state governments necessarily
face a hard budget constraint unlike the central government
– is so important. This obviously puts direct limits
upon the capacity of state governments to fulfil even
their constitutional responsibilities towards their
citizens.
Increasingly,
the powers to raise resources are constrained by the
distribution of revenue-generating powers in the context
of the changing composition of national income. Since
the state governments cannot impose service taxes, and
therefore must exclude the fastest growing segment of
the economy from their resource raising efforts, they
are at a significant disadvantage compared to the central
government in this regard. So the pattern of fiscal
devolution from Centre to States is of the utmost significance
for most developmental issues as well as basic socio-economic
rights of the citizens in the country as a whole.The
basic means of financial transfer is through the successive
Finance Commissions, which are supposed to ensure a
fair and equitable devolution of fiscal resources from
the Centre to States. However, the terms of reference
of recent Finance Commissions have gone beyond the simple
allocation of tax revenues between Centre and different
States according to a given formula, to allowing and
even proposing conditional transfers, even if this goes
against the basic principle of federal devolution. Thus,
the Eleventh Finance Commission proposed a system of
debt relief to states which required them to first pass
fiscal responsibility legislation according to parameters
laid down by the Centre.For all the talk of decentralisation,
this actually amounts to a greater centralisation of
government finances. Direct central allocations to states
are increasingly covered by conditionalities, even if
they are egregious or unsuitable to the state in question.
A case in point is the transfer of funds under the Jawaharlal
Nehru National Urban Renewal Mission (JNNURM), which
requires problematic measures such as the elimination
of stamp duty by recipient state governments. Or they
are so rigid as to make it difficult to adjust the funding
to local requirements, as in the case of the Sarva Shiksha
Abhiyan (SSA) where exactly the same norms for expenditure
are laid down for all states regardless of differing
contexts.Another attempt to undermine federalism and
the authority of elected state governments comes in
the arguments for fiscal provisions by the Centre directly
to panchayats at district level. With norms for expenditure
determined by the Centre, as well as "capacity building"
of panchayat members by the Centre, this amounts to
an extremely centralised notion of decentralisation,
where the real decisions are made at the very top of
national government rather than being delegated to states
and then to panchayats.In this context, what is the
current situation with respect to the fiscal health
of states and financial devolution? Chart 1 describes
the pattern of deficit among all state governments taken
together. It is evident that the severe fiscal crisis
of the states that was so marked in the early years
of this decade is no longer as pervasive. Since 2004
all the major deficit indicators have been declining,
and the revenue and primary deficits are now close to
zero for the states as a whole. Even the fiscal deficit
total is under 3 per cent of GDP.
Chart
1 >>
It is generally supposed that this improved fiscal health
is the reuslt of the Eleventh Finance Commisison’s award,
which is perceived ot have substantially increased grants
to states and also allowed some debt write-off to those
states that agreed to pass the controversial fiscal
responsbility legislation. However, Chart 2 indicates
that such a conclusion is not justified. In fact, the
significant increase has been in tax receipts of the
state governments themselves, which in 2006-07 accounted
for more than 55 per cent of their total fiscal resources.
Chart
2 >>
The share in central taxes has remained small and shown
hardly any increase as a proportion of total receipts.
Even all non-tax receipts (which include grants from
the Centre as the biggest chunk) have not increased
veyr much and remain at less than a quarter of total
receipts. It is worth noting that the share of capital
receipts has declined very sharply in recent years.
Chart
3 >>
The relatively low and even declining share of central
taxes is confimred by the evidence on the states’ share
of central taxes as a proportion of the totla central
tax collection. Chart 3 shows that this has been declining
since the most recent peak of 2001-02, and that the
average of the last three years (2004-05 to 2006-07)
is well below the average of the three-year period of
a decade earlier. All the state government taken together
currently receive just around one quarter of central
tax revenues, even though they are directly responsible
for most of the public service delivery that directly
affects the lives of people.
Chart
4 >>
What of the total financial devolution, that is including
grants and all other mechanisms? In current nominal
terms that has certainly been rising, as indicated by
Chart 4 which show the nominal rate of growth on the
right hand scale. However, as share of GDP of states
they have been mostly stganant in the recent period,
and indicate some evidence of medium-term decline compared
to the early 1990s.
It was noted earlier that capital receipts had been
declining as a percentage of total state governments’
receipts, and stood at only 21 per cent in 2006-07.
Within this, however, the share of market borrowings
increased, as evident from Chart 5 which exmaines the
nature of financing the fiscal deficit for all states.
In the last three years described here there has also
been a sharp increase in use of small svaings (the NSSF
or Natioanl Small Savings Fund) which reflects the shift
in personal savings away from bank deposits to small
savings because of interest rate differentials. This
of course means that state governments have had to pay
relatively higher rates of interest on borrowing even
in the period of lower interest rates on average, but
at least they automatically receive most of these funds.
Evidence from 2007-08 suggests that this was not forthcoming
last year. Meanwhile, loans from the central government
have declined to the point of irrelevance.
Chart
5>>
It is sometimes believed that grant funds, which are
non-interest bearing and supposedly untied, allow a
greater degree of comfort and flexibility to states,
and indeed the Eleventh Finance Commission put more
emphasis on grants for thosereaosns, as well as because
of the perceived decline in aggregate tax-GDP ratios.
However, a substantial proportion of the grants provided
to the States come in the form of Central Schemes and
Centrally Sponsored Schemes.
Chart
6 >>
Chart 6 shows that not only are
these significant, but they have also been increasing
as a proportion of total grants in the recent period.
Strictly speaking, transfers for Central Schemes should
not be included in such grants at all or counted as
part of devolved resources, since they reflect central
government expenditure that is simply administered by
states. Centrally Sponsored Scehemes are also problematic
since they typically require matching expenditure by
states (of varying proportions acording to Scheme) and
are in any case completely determined by the Centre,
in terms of content, structure, format and process.
So they cannot really be described as devolved funds
at all. This is especially the case given the significant
increase in different forms of conditionality that now
accompany most if not all Centrally Sponsored Schemes.
However, it is apparent from Chart 6 that more than
one-fourth of all grants to States come in these centralised
forms.
All this suggests that fiscal federalism still remains
somewhat of an empty promise in India, despite all the
protestations to the contrary. If this is indeed the
case, and the central government continues to control
the bulk of public finances in India, then surely it
should also take more responsibility for the eocnomic
and social outcomes that are determined by poublic spending.
|
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|