|
|
|
|
The
Potential Fall-out of Basel II |
|
Mar
17th 2007, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
The
enhanced Basel guidelines, we had argued in a previous
article (http://www.macroscan.org/fet/mar07/fet030307
Basel_II.htm), would lead to changes in the
structure of the banking sector that would affect bank
behaviour. In addition, Basel II has direct implications
for bank lending. What needs to be considered therefore
is the way these two factors may interact to influence
bank lending. The point to note is that using external
(or at a later stage, internally generated) ratings
to decide the appropriate risk-weights to assesses capital
adequacy, inevitably requires providing banks with a
greater degree of flexibility in deciding their lending
patterns based on pure profit considerations. This makes
it difficult to simultaneously implement a banking policy
that seeks to direct a proportion of lending to specified
sectors taking into account growth and equity objectives.
The effect of changes in banking structure on bank behaviour
can be illustrated by looking at the implications of
the possible expansion of foreign presence. Even with
the diluted regulation that currently is in place, it
is clear that private banks in general and foreign banks
in particular have been lax in meeting regulatory norms.
Principally private and foreign banks have been unwilling
to meet in full the government’s effort to direct credit
to priority sectors and maintain differential interest
rates that involve an element of cross-subsidization.
This implies that any takeover trend led by foreign
investors and banks would have adverse implications
for the priority sectors, especially agriculture.
Second, an increase in foreign bank presence, by subjecting
public sector banks to comparisons of ''profitability''
and ''efficiency'', would force these banks to change
their lending practices as well. In fact, faced with
the demands made on them by the advocates of liberalization
and the effects of competition from the private sector
banks, banks in the public sector are already changing
their lending practices. Public sector banks that accounted
for 79.5 per cent of total assets of all commercial
banks in 2003 earned only 67.2 per cent of aggregate
net profits, whereas the older private sector banks
with 6.5 per cent of total assets earned 8.1 per cent
of aggregate net profits, the new private sector banks
with 6.1 per cent of assets obtained 10 per cent of
the aggregate net profits and foreign banks with just
7.9 per cent of total assets garnered 14.7 per cent
of aggregate net profits.
Among the factors that account for this differential
in profitability, there are two that are important.
One is that the operating expenses for a given volume
of business tend to be higher with public sector banks.
The other is that income generated out of a given volume
of business tends to be lower in the case of the public
sector banks. These are the two areas in which changes
are being made as part of the effort of the public sector
banks to ''match up'' to the performance of private
domestic and foreign banks. Those efforts have increased
demands for a ''level playing field'', implying the
public sector banks too would like to focus on profitable
rather than directed lending. The expansion of foreign
presence would only accelerate this tendency.
These changes in the structure of the banking sector
and the behaviour of banks, which began with liberalization,
would be accelerated by Basel II. Under pressure to
set aside larger volumes of regulatory capital if lending
is to high-risk borrowers and/or low-rated or unrated
borrowers, banks would like to redirect their resources
to safe investments and credit to highly rated borrowers.
This pressure would be all the greater if these banks
have to go public, list their shares and be subject
to shareholder pressure for higher returns. All this
would have a number of implications for growth and equity.
The nature and magnitude of this impact comes through
from an analysis of developments during the period of
reform and the period when Basel I was being implemented.
Consider for example the impact of reform, which, through
its stress on reducing the pre-emption of bank assets
in the form of the cash reserve ratio, the statutory
liquidity ratio and directed credit programmes, was
expected to substantially increase access to credit
for commercial borrowers in the system.
Table 1 >>
Following
the reforms, the credit deposit ratio of commercial
banks as a whole declined substantially from 60.4 per
cent in 1990-91 to 55.9 per cent in 2003-4, despite
a substantial increase in the loanable funds base of
banks through periodic reductions in the CRR and SLR
by the RBI starting in 1992. There are signs of a revival
more recently, driven possibly by the housing and personal
finance boom. It could, of course, be argued that the
earlier decline may have been the result of a decline
in demand for credit from creditworthy borrowers in
the system. However, three facts appear to question
that argument. The first is that the decrease in the
credit deposit ratio has been accompanied by a corresponding
increase in the proportion of risk free government securities
in the banks major earning assets i.e. loans and advances,
and investments. Table 1 reveals that the investment
in government securities as a percentage of total earning
assets for the commercial banking system as a whole
was 22.6 per cent in 1990-91. But it increased to 40.0
per cent in 2003-04. This points to the fact that lending
to the commercial sector may have been displaced by
investments in government securities that were offering
relatively high, near risk-free returns.
Second, under pressure to restructure their asset base
by reducing non-performing assets, public sector banks
may have been reluctant to take on even slightly risky
private sector exposure that could damage their restructuring
effort. This has encouraged the Scheduled Commercial
Banks to hold risk-free government securities far in
excess of that stipulated under Statutory Liquidity
Ratios. The share of public sector banks in 2002-3 in
total investments in government securities of the scheduled
commercial banks was very high (79.17 per cent), when
compared with other sub-groups like Indian private banks
(13.41 per cent), foreign banks (5.7 per cent) and RRBs
(1.74 per cent). Holding government securities enabled
banks to avoid the capital adequacy requirements.
Thus the increased attraction of government securities
in comparison to loans and advances in the reform period
points to the growing risk-aversion on the part of banks,
which might have resulted from the increasingly stringent
prudential regulations such as income recognition, asset
classification, provisioning, capital adequacy norm,
etc. that have been implemented since the adoption of
Basel I norms. It needs to be noted here that government
securities were classified as risk-free and thus did
not carry any provisioning requirements.
In the event, the experience of implementing even Basel
1 has not been positive from the point of view of credit
delivery. This would worsen after Basel II. The preference
of banks for government securities and the increased
risk-aversion of banks following the adoption of Basel
II would adversely affect credit to agriculture and
small scale industries.
Banking Reform and Priority Sector Credit
In fact, past experience indicates that changing bank
behaviour in the wake of institutional and regulatory
reform has in particular affected credit delivery to
the priority sectors. The process of directing credit
to what were ''priority'' sectors in the government’s
view was facilitated by the nationalization of leading
banks, since it would have been difficult to convince
private players with a choice of investing in more lucrative
activities to take to a risky activity like banking
where returns were regulated. Nationalization was therefore
in keeping with a banking policy that implied pre-empting
banking resources for the government through mechanisms
like the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR), which defined
the proportion of deposits that need to be diverted
to holding specified government securities, as well
as for priority sectors through the imposition of lending
targets. An obvious corollary is that if the government
gradually denationalizes the banking system, its ability
to continue with socially-motivated and inclusive banking
and with policies such as directed credit and differential
interest rates would be substantially undermined.
''Denationalization'', which takes the form of both easing
the entry of domestic and foreign players as well as
the disinvestment of equity in private sector banks,
forces a change in banking practices in two ways. First,
private players would be unsatisfied with returns that
are available within a regulated framework, so that
the government and the central bank would have to dilute
or dismantle these regulatory measures as is happening
in the case of priority lending as well as restrictions
on banking activities in India. Second, even public
sector banks find that as private domestic and foreign
banks, particularly the latter, lure away the most lucrative
banking clients because of the special services and
terms they are able to offer, they have to seek new
sources of finance, new activities and new avenues for
investments, so that they can shore up their interest
incomes as well as revenues from various fee-based activities.
As a result, since 1991 there has been a reversal of
the trends in the ratio of directed credit to total
bank credit and the proportion thereof going to the
agricultural sector, even though there has been no known
formal decision by government on this score. At the
same time, attempts have been made in recent years to
dilute the norms of whatever remains of priority sector
bank lending. Thus, while the authorities have allowed
the target for priority sector lending to remain untouched,
they have widened its coverage. At the same time, shortfalls
relative to targets have been overlooked.
In agriculture, both direct and indirect advances to
agriculture were clubbed together for meeting the agricultural
sub-target of 18 per cent in 1993, subject to the stipulation
however that "indirect" lending to agriculture
must not exceed one-fourth of that lending sub-target
or 4.5 per cent of net bank credit. It was also decided
to include indirect agricultural advances exceeding
4.5 per cent of net bank credit into the overall target
of 40 per cent. The definition of priority sector itself
was also widened to include financing of distribution
of inputs for agriculture and allied sectors with the
ceiling raised to Rs. 5 lakh initially and Rs. 15 lakh
subsequently. Further, financing of distribution of
inputs for allied activities such as dairy, poultry
and piggery up to Rs. 5 lakh were also made eligible
for treatment as indirect agricultural advances. Finally,
the scope of direct agricultural advances under priority
sector lending was widened to include all short-term
advances to traditional plantations including tea, coffee,
rubber, and spices, irrespective of the size of the
holdings.
So far as small scale industries were concerned, the
coverage for priority sector lending was extended by
re-defining the sector in terms of the level of investments
in plant and machinery together with an increase in
working capital limits. Initially, the SSI sector included
those industries whose investment and machinery did
not exceed Rs. 35 lakh. In the case of ancillary units,
the investment limit was Rs. 45 lakh. In May, 1994,
these limits were raised to Rs. 60 lakh and Rs. 70 lakh
respectively. This has gone up to Rs. 3 crore in some
cases. All advances to SSIs as per the revised definition
were to be treated as priority sector advances which
indirectly encouraged term finance loans.
It is in the light of this that the trends in priority
sector lending during the post liberalisation period
of 1991-2004 needs to be understood. Priority sector
lending as a proportion of net bank credit, after reaching
the target of 40 per cent in 1991, had been continuously
falling short of target till 1996. It has subsequently
been in excess of the target for the reasons specified
above, and stood at 44 per cent in 2004, which was mainly
due to the inclusion of funds provided to RRBs by their
sponsoring banks that were eligible to be treated as
priority sector advances. Advances to agriculture on
the other hand declined from 16.4 per cent of net bank
credit in 1991 to 15.4 per cent in 2004, well below
the target of 18 per cent of net bank credit. Within
the category of agricultural advances, the growth of
indirect finance has been much faster than direct finance
to agriculturists. Indirect finance to agriculture includes
lending to various intermediary agencies assisting the
farmers as also investment in special bonds issued by
NABARD and the Rural Electrification Corporation (REC).
It also includes deposits placed by banks in RIDF.
In sum, the principal mechanism of directed credit to
the priority sector that aimed at using the banking
system as an instrument for development is increasingly
proving to be a casualty of the reform effort. And methods
are being found to conceal this trend by window-dressing
the evidence of achievement with regard to priority
sector lending.
The functioning of the system of credit delivery by
scheduled commercial banks, the largest component of
the financial sector in India, is a good example of
the extent and nature of the neglect of agriculture,
small-scale industries and small borrowers, the correction
of which is most crucial. According to a study undertaken
by the EPW Research Foundation the share of agriculture
in total bank credit had steadily increased under impulse
of bank nationalization and reached 18 per cent towards
the end of the 1980s, but thereafter the achievement
has been almost completely reversed and the share of
the agricultural sector in credit has dipped to less
than 10 per cent in the late 1990s-a ratio that had
prevailed in the early 1970s. Even the number of farm
loan accounts with scheduled commercials banks has declined
in absolute terms from 27.74 million in March 1992 to
20.84 million in March 2003.
Further, overall credit to the small sector including
the SSIs fell from 17.3 percent of net bank credit from
PSBs in 1999-2000 to 7 percent in 2003-04. Of the sum
lent to the SSIs, 40 percent is earmarked as advances
to 'Tiny’ units (those which has investment less than
Rs 50 lakhs), at below-PLR interest rates. However,
interest rates on all other SSI units as well as those
on 'other loans 'in the priority category have been
liberalized since 1992. It is known that banks lend
to SMEs at a higher interest rate and that these loans
are heavily collaterised. Not surprisingly, the Third
Census of Small industries conducted recently revealed
that shortage of working capital was a major factor
accounting for closure of industrial units in the SSI
sector.
Unfortunately the decision to continue with liberalization
and institutionalizing it through the adoption of the
more stringent norms would only encourage the diversion
of credit to higher rated corporates and the retail
lending sector, aggravating the adverse consequences
of past financial reform and the adoption of Basel I.
Much of the so-called risk-aversion of banks which goes
against loans to the small and medium industries have
their origin in the quick adoption of the Basel approved
credit risk adjusted ratios (CRAR) for capital. Implementing
Basel II will further accentuate the ongoing trend by
moving credit away from agriculture and industrial units
in the small sector.
In addition to all of this, it is known that implementation
of Basel II norms would introduce pro-cyclical elements
into developing economies. Critics have argued that
the drive for riskweights to more accurately reflect
probability of default (PD) is inherently pro-cyclical
in that, during an upturn, average PD will fall, reducing
incentives to lend. Conversely, during a downturn, average
PD will increase (due to more difficult economic circumstances)
and, in consequence, a credit crunch may develop with
all but the most highly rated borrowers having difficulty
attracting funds.
|
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|