The
enhanced Basel guidelines, we had argued in a previous article (http://www.macroscan.org/fet/mar07/fet030307Basel_II.htm),
would lead to changes in the structure of the banking sector that would
affect bank behaviour. In addition, Basel II has direct implications for
bank lending. What needs to be considered therefore is the way these two
factors may interact to influence bank lending. The point to note is that
using external (or at a later stage, internally generated) ratings to
decide the appropriate risk-weights to assesses capital adequacy, inevitably
requires providing banks with a greater degree of flexibility in deciding
their lending patterns based on pure profit considerations. This makes
it difficult to simultaneously implement a banking policy that seeks to
direct a proportion of lending to specified sectors taking into account
growth and equity objectives.
The effect of changes in banking structure on bank behaviour can be illustrated
by looking at the implications of the possible expansion of foreign presence.
Even with the diluted regulation that currently is in place, it is clear
that private banks in general and foreign banks in particular have been
lax in meeting regulatory norms. Principally private and foreign banks
have been unwilling to meet in full the government’s effort to direct
credit to priority sectors and maintain differential interest rates that
involve an element of cross-subsidization. This implies that any takeover
trend led by foreign investors and banks would have adverse implications
for the priority sectors, especially agriculture.
Second, an increase in foreign bank presence, by subjecting public sector
banks to comparisons of ''profitability'' and ''efficiency'', would force
these banks to change their lending practices as well. In fact, faced
with the demands made on them by the advocates of liberalization and the
effects of competition from the private sector banks, banks in the public
sector are already changing their lending practices. Public sector banks
that accounted for 79.5 per cent of total assets of all commercial banks
in 2003 earned only 67.2 per cent of aggregate net profits, whereas the
older private sector banks with 6.5 per cent of total assets earned 8.1
per cent of aggregate net profits, the new private sector banks with 6.1
per cent of assets obtained 10 per cent of the aggregate net profits and
foreign banks with just 7.9 per cent of total assets garnered 14.7 per
cent of aggregate net profits.
Among the factors that account for this differential in profitability,
there are two that are important. One is that the operating expenses for
a given volume of business tend to be higher with public sector banks.
The other is that income generated out of a given volume of business tends
to be lower in the case of the public sector banks. These are the two
areas in which changes are being made as part of the effort of the public
sector banks to ''match up'' to the performance of private domestic and
foreign banks. Those efforts have increased demands for a ''level playing
field'', implying the public sector banks too would like to focus on profitable
rather than directed lending. The expansion of foreign presence would
only accelerate this tendency.
These changes in the structure of the banking sector and the behaviour
of banks, which began with liberalization, would be accelerated by Basel
II. Under pressure to set aside larger volumes of regulatory capital if
lending is to high-risk borrowers and/or low-rated or unrated borrowers,
banks would like to redirect their resources to safe investments and credit
to highly rated borrowers. This pressure would be all the greater if these
banks have to go public, list their shares and be subject to shareholder
pressure for higher returns. All this would have a number of implications
for growth and equity.
The nature and magnitude of this impact comes through from an analysis
of developments during the period of reform and the period when Basel
I was being implemented. Consider for example the impact of reform, which,
through its stress on reducing the pre-emption of bank assets in the form
of the cash reserve ratio, the statutory liquidity ratio and directed
credit programmes, was expected to substantially increase access to credit
for commercial borrowers in the system.
Table
1: Credit Deposit Ratio and Investment in Government Securities
as percentage of Total Earning Assets during 1990-91 to 2003-04
(For scheduled commercial banks) |
Year |
Credit
Deposit Ratio |
Investment
in Govt. Securities
(as percentage to total earning assets) |
1990-91 |
60.4 |
22.6 |
1991-92 |
54.4 |
24.3 |
1992-93 |
56.6 |
25.6 |
1993-94 |
52.2 |
28.4 |
1994-95 |
54.7 |
27.0 |
1995-96 |
58.6 |
27.2 |
1996-97 |
55.1 |
29.5 |
1997-98 |
54.1 |
29.9 |
1998-99 |
51.7 |
30.9 |
1999-00 |
53.6 |
32.9 |
2000-01 |
53.1 |
33.9 |
2001-02 |
53.4 |
36.0 |
2002-03 |
58.3 |
37.5 |
2003-04 |
55.9 |
40.0 |
2004-05 |
62.9 |
37.2 |
Figures
in parentheses exclude the impact of mergers on May 3, 2002 and the impact
of conversion of a non-
banking entity into a banking entity on October 11, 2004.
Source: Estimated from TABLE 47 : Scheduled Commercial Banks - Select
Aaggregates in RBI, Handbook of Statistics on Indian Economy.
Following
the reforms, the credit deposit ratio of commercial banks as a whole declined
substantially from 60.4 per cent in 1990-91 to 55.9 per cent in 2003-4,
despite a substantial increase in the loanable funds base of banks through
periodic reductions in the CRR and SLR by the RBI starting in 1992. There
are signs of a revival more recently, driven possibly by the housing and
personal finance boom. It could, of course, be argued that the earlier
decline may have been the result of a decline in demand for credit from
creditworthy borrowers in the system. However, three facts appear to question
that argument. The first is that the decrease in the credit deposit ratio
has been accompanied by a corresponding increase in the proportion of
risk free government securities in the banks major earning assets i.e.
loans and advances, and investments. Table 1 reveals that the investment
in government securities as a percentage of total earning assets for the
commercial banking system as a whole was 22.6 per cent in 1990-91. But
it increased to 40.0 per cent in 2003-04. This points to the fact that
lending to the commercial sector may have been displaced by investments
in government securities that were offering relatively high, near risk-free
returns.
Second, under pressure to restructure their asset base by reducing non-performing
assets, public sector banks may have been reluctant to take on even slightly
risky private sector exposure that could damage their restructuring effort.
This has encouraged the Scheduled Commercial Banks to hold risk-free government
securities far in excess of that stipulated under Statutory Liquidity
Ratios. The share of public sector banks in 2002-3 in total investments
in government securities of the scheduled commercial banks was very high
(79.17 per cent), when compared with other sub-groups like Indian private
banks (13.41 per cent), foreign banks (5.7 per cent) and RRBs (1.74 per
cent). Holding government securities enabled banks to avoid the capital
adequacy requirements.
Thus the increased attraction of government securities in comparison to
loans and advances in the reform period points to the growing risk-aversion
on the part of banks, which might have resulted from the increasingly
stringent prudential regulations such as income recognition, asset classification,
provisioning, capital adequacy norm, etc. that have been implemented since
the adoption of Basel I norms. It needs to be noted here that government
securities were classified as risk-free and thus did not carry any provisioning
requirements.
In the event, the experience of implementing even Basel 1 has not been
positive from the point of view of credit delivery. This would worsen
after Basel II. The preference of banks for government securities and
the increased risk-aversion of banks following the adoption of Basel II
would adversely affect credit to agriculture and small scale industries.
Banking Reform and Priority Sector Credit
In fact, past experience indicates that changing bank behaviour in the
wake of institutional and regulatory reform has in particular affected
credit delivery to the priority sectors. The process of directing credit
to what were ''priority'' sectors in the government’s view was facilitated
by the nationalization of leading banks, since it would have been difficult
to convince private players with a choice of investing in more lucrative
activities to take to a risky activity like banking where returns were
regulated. Nationalization was therefore in keeping with a banking policy
that implied pre-empting banking resources for the government through
mechanisms like the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR), which defined the
proportion of deposits that need to be diverted to holding specified government
securities, as well as for priority sectors through the imposition of
lending targets. An obvious corollary is that if the government gradually
denationalizes the banking system, its ability to continue with socially-motivated
and inclusive banking and with policies such as directed credit and differential
interest rates would be substantially undermined.
''Denationalization'', which takes the form of both easing the entry of
domestic and foreign players as well as the disinvestment of equity in
private sector banks, forces a change in banking practices in two ways.
First, private players would be unsatisfied with returns that are available
within a regulated framework, so that the government and the central bank
would have to dilute or dismantle these regulatory measures as is happening
in the case of priority lending as well as restrictions on banking activities
in India. Second, even public sector banks find that as private domestic
and foreign banks, particularly the latter, lure away the most lucrative
banking clients because of the special services and terms they are able
to offer, they have to seek new sources of finance, new activities and
new avenues for investments, so that they can shore up their interest
incomes as well as revenues from various fee-based activities.
As a result, since 1991 there has been a reversal of the trends in the
ratio of directed credit to total bank credit and the proportion thereof
going to the agricultural sector, even though there has been no known
formal decision by government on this score. At the same time, attempts
have been made in recent years to dilute the norms of whatever remains
of priority sector bank lending. Thus, while the authorities have allowed
the target for priority sector lending to remain untouched, they have
widened its coverage. At the same time, shortfalls relative to targets
have been overlooked.
In agriculture, both direct and indirect advances to agriculture were
clubbed together for meeting the agricultural sub-target of 18 per cent
in 1993, subject to the stipulation however that "indirect"
lending to agriculture must not exceed one-fourth of that lending sub-target
or 4.5 per cent of net bank credit. It was also decided to include indirect
agricultural advances exceeding 4.5 per cent of net bank credit into the
overall target of 40 per cent. The definition of priority sector itself
was also widened to include financing of distribution of inputs for agriculture
and allied sectors with the ceiling raised to Rs. 5 lakh initially and
Rs. 15 lakh subsequently. Further, financing of distribution of inputs
for allied activities such as dairy, poultry and piggery up to Rs. 5 lakh
were also made eligible for treatment as indirect agricultural advances.
Finally, the scope of direct agricultural advances under priority sector
lending was widened to include all short-term advances to traditional
plantations including tea, coffee, rubber, and spices, irrespective of
the size of the holdings.
So far as small scale industries were concerned, the coverage for priority
sector lending was extended by re-defining the sector in terms of the
level of investments in plant and machinery together with an increase
in working capital limits. Initially, the SSI sector included those industries
whose investment and machinery did not exceed Rs. 35 lakh. In the case
of ancillary units, the investment limit was Rs. 45 lakh. In May, 1994,
these limits were raised to Rs. 60 lakh and Rs. 70 lakh respectively.
This has gone up to Rs. 3 crore in some cases. All advances to SSIs as
per the revised definition were to be treated as priority sector advances
which indirectly encouraged term finance loans.
It is in the light of this that the trends in priority sector lending
during the post liberalisation period of 1991-2004 needs to be understood.
Priority sector lending as a proportion of net bank credit, after reaching
the target of 40 per cent in 1991, had been continuously falling short
of target till 1996. It has subsequently been in excess of the target
for the reasons specified above, and stood at 44 per cent in 2004, which
was mainly due to the inclusion of funds provided to RRBs by their sponsoring
banks that were eligible to be treated as priority sector advances. Advances
to agriculture on the other hand declined from 16.4 per cent of net bank
credit in 1991 to 15.4 per cent in 2004, well below the target of 18 per
cent of net bank credit. Within the category of agricultural advances,
the growth of indirect finance has been much faster than direct finance
to agriculturists. Indirect finance to agriculture includes lending to
various intermediary agencies assisting the farmers as also investment
in special bonds issued by NABARD and the Rural Electrification Corporation
(REC). It also includes deposits placed by banks in RIDF.
In sum, the principal mechanism of directed credit to the priority sector
that aimed at using the banking system as an instrument for development
is increasingly proving to be a casualty of the reform effort. And methods
are being found to conceal this trend by window-dressing the evidence
of achievement with regard to priority sector lending.
The functioning of the system of credit delivery by scheduled commercial
banks, the largest component of the financial sector in India, is a good
example of the extent and nature of the neglect of agriculture, small-scale
industries and small borrowers, the correction of which is most crucial.
According to a study undertaken by the EPW Research Foundation the share
of agriculture in total bank credit had steadily increased under impulse
of bank nationalization and reached 18 per cent towards the end of the
1980s, but thereafter the achievement has been almost completely reversed
and the share of the agricultural sector in credit has dipped to less
than 10 per cent in the late 1990s-a ratio that had prevailed in the early
1970s. Even the number of farm loan accounts with scheduled commercials
banks has declined in absolute terms from 27.74 million in March 1992
to 20.84 million in March 2003.
Further, overall credit to the small sector including the SSIs fell from
17.3 percent of net bank credit from PSBs in 1999-2000 to 7 percent in
2003-04. Of the sum lent to the SSIs, 40 percent is earmarked as advances
to 'Tiny’ units (those which has investment less than Rs 50 lakhs), at
below-PLR interest rates. However, interest rates on all other SSI units
as well as those on 'other loans 'in the priority category have been liberalized
since 1992. It is known that banks lend to SMEs at a higher interest rate
and that these loans are heavily collaterised. Not surprisingly, the Third
Census of Small industries conducted recently revealed that shortage of
working capital was a major factor accounting for closure of industrial
units in the SSI sector.
Unfortunately the decision to continue with liberalization and institutionalizing
it through the adoption of the more stringent norms would only encourage
the diversion of credit to higher rated corporates and the retail lending
sector, aggravating the adverse consequences of past financial reform
and the adoption of Basel I. Much of the so-called risk-aversion of banks
which goes against loans to the small and medium industries have their
origin in the quick adoption of the Basel approved credit risk adjusted
ratios (CRAR) for capital. Implementing Basel II will further accentuate
the ongoing trend by moving credit away from agriculture and industrial
units in the small sector.
In addition to all of this, it is known that implementation of Basel II
norms would introduce pro-cyclical elements into developing economies.
Critics have argued that the drive for riskweights to more accurately
reflect probability of default (PD) is inherently pro-cyclical in that,
during an upturn, average PD will fall, reducing incentives to lend. Conversely,
during a downturn, average PD will increase (due to more difficult economic
circumstances) and, in consequence, a credit crunch may develop with all
but the most highly rated borrowers having difficulty attracting funds.
|