It is notable that
despite significant differences across the countries of South Asia in
terms of
size,
resource endowment, particular social and political configurations,
all of these economies share certain structural characteristics. These
include: the presence of a high degree of underemployment; a strong
dualism between organized and unorganized sectors, especially in
manufacturing, which sometimes (but not always) translates into the
dualism between large-scale and small-scale sectors; the continuing
significance of agriculture as a major employer; the emergence of services
as the largest employers, often as a refuge sector; the involvement of a
large share of the workforce in what is essentially low-productivity
employment.
But in addition to these, what is more remarkable is the apparent
synchronicity of policies and processes across the region, despite very
differing social and political pressures. All the economies of the region,
for the first few decades after independence, adopted import-substituting
industrialization strategies, with the attendant development of some
industry and associated dualism in the economy, as well as regulation of
much economic activity.
From the 1980s onwards, all of them moved, in varying degrees, to a
strategy of development based on export-orientation, liberalization and
privatization based on the marketist neoliberal economic paradigm. The
process could be said to have started in South Asia with the Sri Lankan
government of Jayawardene moving towards liberalization and dismantling of
the earlier universal food security system, in the late 1970s and early
1980s.
Subsequently, and more strongly in the early 1990s, all the governments in
the region (barring that of Nepal, which had very a different position)
went through fairly comprehensive policies of internal
liberalisation-reduction of direct state responsibility for a range of
goods and services-and privatization.
By the turn of the century, most of the important economies in South Asia
had undergone
-
substantial reduction in direct state control in terms of administered
prices, regulation of economic activity;
-
privatization of state assets, often in controversial circumstances;
-
rationalization (usually also a euphemism for reduction) of direct and
indirect tax rates that became associated with declining tax-GDP ratios;
-
attempts (typically unsuccessful) to reduce fiscal deficits which
usually involved cutting back on public productive investment as well as
certain types of social expenditure, reducing subsidies to farmers and
increasing user charges for public services and utilities;
-
trade
liberalization, involving shifts from quantitative restrictions to
tariffs and typically sharp reductions in the average rate of tariff
protection;
-
financial liberalization involving reductions in directed credit,
freeing of interest rate ceilings and other measures that raised the
cost of borrowing, including for the government;
-
moving to market determined exchange rates and liberalization of current
account transactions;
-
allowing some degree of capital account liberalization, including easing
of rules for Foreign Direct Investment, allowing non-residents to hold
domestic financial assets and providing easier access to foreign
commercial borrowing by domestic firms.
This commonality of
policy experience meant in turn that outcomes were also quite similar,
despite the very different initial conditions in different economies. Some
of these outcomes are discussed in detail below.
Pakistan
The economy of
Pakistan
is viewed internationally as having a reasonably good rate of output
growth. This perception is more a reflection of the general slowdown in
economic growth across the world, than in any improvement in Pakistan's
growth performance per se. It is true that for the period 1960–90,
Pakistan's
growth was high for a low-income country, at around 6 per cent per annum
with a 2 per cent variation. However, the 1990s involved a significant
deceleration of growth in Pakistan, especially in certain sectors such as
manufacturing.
Further, such growth has been associated with very inadequate performance
in terms of human development indicators. William Easterly (2001) has
argued that Pakistan's pattern is indicative of 'growth without
development', because despite its 'respectable' per capita growth over the
second half of the twentieth century, the country has 'systematically
underperformed' on most social and political indicators, such as
education, health, sanitation, fertility, gender equality, corruption,
political instability and violence, and democracy. Significantly, such
output growth has also been associated with much lower employment growth,
at the trend rate of only 2 per cent per annum for the long period of
1960–99.
During the recent years, a number of features of the economic growth
process in Pakistan are worth noting. First, is the very high degree of
volatility of growth, with very significant fluctuations over the years,
and a trend deceleration evident in the 1990s. Second, is that this growth
has been based largely on unsustainable public expenditure using a
build-up of public debt that has already reached problematic levels. Total
debt-servicing (of external and internal debt together) already accounts
for more than 71 per cent of current government revenues, and future
expansion cannot rely on similar debt-driven public spending alone.
Third, is the very high presence of underemployment or disguised
unemployment. The Labour Force Survey data suggest underemployment rates
of 13.3 per cent in rural areas and 6.3 per cent in urban areas in the
mid-1990s, but these are likely to be underestimates.
Fourth, is the fact that there appears to be relatively less direct
relation between growth and employment generation. As Chart 1 indicates,
output growth was relatively low in the 1970s. It increased in the 1980s
and dropped again in the 1990s. But employment growth followed the
opposite pattern, being at its highest at 3 per cent over the 1970s and
dropping to 2 per cent in the next two decades. Nomaan Majid (2002) finds
a total break between growth and employment in the period after the
mid-1980s, and particularly in the period after the imposition of an
International Monetary Programme (IMF)-induced Structural Adjustment
Programme in 1987–88.
Chart 1 >>
It is apparent that in terms of output growth,
manufacturing (Chart 3) was the lead sector over all three periods, and
agriculture (Chart 2) contributed progressively less over time. In terms
of employment growth, manufacturing led during the low growth phase of the
1970s, and in the 1990s when output growth rates declined once again,
employment growth in manufacturing was actually negative.
Chart 2 >>
Chart 3 >>
Majid
(2000) suggests that the overall break between output and employment
therefore seems to be associated more with the manufacturing sector, and
that agriculture and construction (Chart 4) may have become residual
'refuge' sectors in the most recent period. This would also explain
negative productivity growth in construction in the 1990s.
Char 4 >>
This
analysis implies that the manufacturing sector is the key to the
explanation of the poor employment performance of the past. Manufacturing
in Pakistan, as in most other developing nations, is characterized by a
high degree of dualism. There is a large-scale sector that dominates
output (producing two-thirds of the value added in manufacturing) but
employs only 17 per cent of manufacturing workers, and a small-scale
sector that dominates employment (with 83 per cent of the manufacturing
workforce) but accounts for only one-third of the manufacturing value
added.
The output and employment shares of these two categories have been
remarkably stable over time. The small-scale sector operating under major
and increasing constraints and with huge disadvantages, has been
relatively moribund in the last decade, and shows all the characteristics
of a refuge labour sector. Meanwhile, the large-scale sector has been
plagued by excess capacity (due to deficient aggregate demand resulting
from deflationary structural adjustment policies, and import penetration)
as well as by increasing capital intensity and in capital productivity due
to newer technologies that have had the effect of reducing labour demand.
So, much as had occurred in India over the same period, investment and
output growth in manufacturing in Pakistan tended to be capital-augmenting
and labour-displacing. Since manufacturing was the lead sector in
employment generation, this then affected the employment possibilities
elsewhere in the economy, and explains both the persistence of
low-productivity employment in the residual sectors and the low and
declining rates of labour force participation in Pakistan.
The significance of deflationary macro-policies in affecting both growth
and employment in Pakistan has already been mentioned. A very major and
direct role was played in this case by the constraints imposed on public
investment. The investment–GDP ratio declined from 17.3 per cent in
1998–89 to 14.7 per cent in 2000–01, and this was entirely due to the
collapse in public investment from 8.5 per cent of GDP to 5.6 per cent
over the same period.
Private investment, which is strongly interlinked with public investment
and expenditure, faced a deficiency of demand as a result, and did not
rise to meet the emerging slack. In addition, various other elements of
the structural adjustment programme operated to reduce average growth
rates, accelerate inflation, and thereby increase unemployment and
poverty. The standard package of structural reforms included privatization
of public assets, ceilings on wages and employment in the public sector,
cuts in subsidies, cuts in development expenditure, including on 'social
sectors', increases in user charges for public utilities and services and
frequent devaluation.
This last feature also had the unintended consequence of reducing the
inflow of remittances from foreign workers, which has been an important
source of sustenance of Pakistan's balance of payments. (Anwar 2001).
Thus, ironically, the macroeconomic strategy based on Structural
Adjustment Programmes imposed and approved by the IMF and World Bank
supposedly to change the structure of the economy so as to improve the
balance of payments, control inflation and revive growth, had the opposite
effects in practice.
Inadequate employment generation and persistence of low productivity
employment in most sectors inevitably feed into and even increase levels
of poverty. In Pakistan, there is general agreement that the incidence of
poverty has increased over the 1990s, as the combination of deflationary
macro-economic measures and de-industrialization following upon trade
liberalization has made itself felt. Chart 5 describes the broad trends in
poverty measured by the head count ratio.
Chart 5 >>