It is notable that
despite significant differences across the countries of South Asia in
terms of
size,
resource endowment, particular social and political configurations,
all
of these economies share certain structural characteristics. These
include: the presence of a high degree of underemployment; a strong
dualism between organized and unorganized sectors, especially in
manufacturing, which sometimes (but not always) translates into the
dualism between large-scale and small-scale sectors; the continuing
significance of agriculture as a major employer; the emergence of
services as the largest employers, often as a refuge sector; the
involvement of a large share of the workforce in what is essentially
low-productivity employment.
But in addition to these, what is more remarkable is the apparent
synchronicity of policies and processes across the region, despite very
differing social and political pressures. All the economies of the
region, for the first few decades after independence, adopted
import-substituting industrialization strategies, with the attendant
development of some industry and associated dualism in the economy, as
well as regulation of much economic activity.
From the 1980s onwards, all of them moved, in varying degrees, to a
strategy of development based on export-orientation, liberalization and
privatization based on the marketist neoliberal economic paradigm. The
process could be said to have started in South Asia with the Sri Lankan
government of Jayawardene moving towards liberalization and dismantling
of the earlier universal food security system, in the late 1970s and
early 1980s.
Subsequently, and more strongly in the early 1990s, all the governments
in the region (barring that of Nepal, which had very a different
position) went through fairly comprehensive policies of internal
liberalisation-reduction of direct state responsibility for a range of
goods and services-and privatization.
By the turn of the century, most of the important economies in South
Asia had undergone
-
substantial reduction in direct state control in terms of administered
prices, regulation of economic activity;
-
privatization of state assets, often in controversial circumstances;
-
rationalization (usually also a euphemism for reduction) of direct and
indirect tax rates that became associated with declining tax-GDP ratios;
-
attempts (typically unsuccessful) to reduce fiscal deficits which
usually involved cutting back on public productive investment as well as
certain types of social expenditure, reducing subsidies to farmers and
increasing user charges for public services and utilities;
-
trade
liberalization, involving shifts from quantitative restrictions to
tariffs and typically sharp reductions in the average rate of tariff
protection;
-
financial liberalization involving reductions in directed credit,
freeing of interest rate ceilings and other measures that raised the
cost of borrowing, including for the government;
-
moving to market determined exchange rates and liberalization of current
account transactions;
-
allowing some degree of capital account liberalization, including easing
of rules for Foreign Direct Investment, allowing non-residents to hold
domestic financial assets and providing easier access to foreign
commercial borrowing by domestic firms.
This commonality of
policy experience meant in turn that outcomes were also quite similar,
despite the very different initial conditions in different economies.
Some of these outcomes are discussed in detail below.
Pakistan
The economy of
Pakistan
is viewed internationally as having a reasonably good rate of output
growth. This perception is more a reflection of the general slowdown in
economic growth across the world, than in any improvement in Pakistan's
growth performance per se. It is true that for the period
1960–90, Pakistan's
growth was high for a low-income country, at around 6 per cent per annum
with a 2 per cent variation. However, the 1990s involved a significant
deceleration of growth in Pakistan, especially in certain sectors such
as manufacturing.
Further, such growth has been associated with very inadequate
performance in terms of human development indicators. William Easterly
(2001) has argued that Pakistan's pattern is indicative of 'growth
without development', because despite its 'respectable' per capita
growth over the second half of the twentieth century, the country has
'systematically underperformed' on most social and political indicators,
such as education, health, sanitation, fertility, gender equality,
corruption, political instability and violence, and democracy.
Significantly, such output growth has also been associated with much
lower employment growth, at the trend rate of only 2 per cent per annum
for the long period of 1960–99.
During the recent years, a number of features of the economic growth
process in Pakistan are worth noting. First, is the very high degree of
volatility of growth, with very significant fluctuations over the years,
and a trend deceleration evident in the 1990s. Second, is that this
growth has been based largely on unsustainable public expenditure using
a build-up of public debt that has already reached problematic levels.
Total debt-servicing (of external and internal debt together) already
accounts for more than 71 per cent of current government revenues, and
future expansion cannot rely on similar debt-driven public spending
alone.
Third, is the very high presence of underemployment or disguised
unemployment. The Labour Force Survey data suggest underemployment rates
of 13.3 per cent in rural areas and 6.3 per cent in urban areas in the
mid-1990s, but these are likely to be underestimates.
Fourth, is the fact that there appears to be relatively less direct
relation between growth and employment generation. As Chart 1 indicates,
output growth was relatively low in the 1970s. It increased in the 1980s
and dropped again in the 1990s. But employment growth followed the
opposite pattern, being at its highest at 3 per cent over the 1970s and
dropping to 2 per cent in the next two decades. Nomaan Majid (2002)
finds a total break between growth and employment in the period after
the mid-1980s, and particularly in the period after the imposition of an
International Monetary Programme (IMF)-induced Structural Adjustment
Programme in 1987–88.
It is apparent that in terms of output growth, manufacturing (Chart 3)
was the lead sector over all three periods, and agriculture (Chart 2)
contributed progressively less over time. In terms of employment growth,
manufacturing led during the low growth phase of the 1970s, and in the
1990s when output growth rates declined once again, employment growth in
manufacturing was actually negative.
Majid
(2000) suggests that the overall break between output and employment
therefore seems to be associated more with the manufacturing sector, and
that agriculture and construction (Chart 4) may have become residual
'refuge' sectors in the most recent period. This would also explain
negative productivity growth in construction in the 1990s.
This
analysis implies that the manufacturing sector is the key to the
explanation of the poor employment performance of the past.
Manufacturing in Pakistan, as in most other developing nations, is
characterized by a high degree of dualism. There is a large-scale sector
that dominates output (producing two-thirds of the value added in
manufacturing) but employs only 17 per cent of manufacturing workers,
and a small-scale sector that dominates employment (with 83 per cent of
the manufacturing workforce) but accounts for only one-third of the
manufacturing value added.
The output and employment shares of these two categories have been
remarkably stable over time. The small-scale sector operating under
major and increasing constraints and with huge disadvantages, has been
relatively moribund in the last decade, and shows all the
characteristics of a refuge labour sector. Meanwhile, the large-scale
sector has been plagued by excess capacity (due to deficient aggregate
demand resulting from deflationary structural adjustment policies, and
import penetration) as well as by increasing capital intensity and in
capital productivity due to newer technologies that have had the effect
of reducing labour demand.
So, much as had occurred in India over the same period, investment and
output growth in manufacturing in Pakistan tended to be
capital-augmenting and labour-displacing. Since manufacturing was the
lead sector in employment generation, this then affected the employment
possibilities elsewhere in the economy, and explains both the
persistence of low-productivity employment in the residual sectors and
the low and declining rates of labour force participation in Pakistan.
The significance of deflationary macro-policies in affecting both growth
and employment in Pakistan has already been mentioned. A very major and
direct role was played in this case by the constraints imposed on public
investment. The investment–GDP ratio declined from 17.3 per cent in
1998–89 to 14.7 per cent in 2000–01, and this was entirely due to the
collapse in public investment from 8.5 per cent of GDP to 5.6 per cent
over the same period.
Private investment, which is strongly interlinked with public investment
and expenditure, faced a deficiency of demand as a result, and did not
rise to meet the emerging slack. In addition, various other elements of
the structural adjustment programme operated to reduce average growth
rates, accelerate inflation, and thereby increase unemployment and
poverty. The standard package of structural reforms included
privatization of public assets, ceilings on wages and employment in the
public sector, cuts in subsidies, cuts in development expenditure,
including on 'social sectors', increases in user charges for public
utilities and services and frequent devaluation.
This last feature also had the unintended consequence of reducing the
inflow of remittances from foreign workers, which has been an important
source of sustenance of Pakistan's balance of payments. (Anwar 2001).
Thus, ironically, the macroeconomic strategy based on Structural
Adjustment Programmes imposed and approved by the IMF and World Bank
supposedly to change the structure of the economy so as to improve the
balance of payments, control inflation and revive growth, had the
opposite effects in practice.
Inadequate employment generation and persistence of low productivity
employment in most sectors inevitably feed into and even increase levels
of poverty. In Pakistan, there is general agreement that the incidence
of poverty has increased over the 1990s, as the combination of
deflationary macro-economic measures and de-industrialization following
upon trade liberalization has made itself felt. Chart 5 describes the
broad trends in poverty measured by the head count ratio.
It is
noteworthy that the Structural Adjustment Programme inspired by the IMF
(which the IMF itself termed as a 'success') began in 1987–88, after
which the incidence of poverty has been increasing. There are various
reasons behind this, most of which relate to the direct and indirect
effects of the macro-economic strategy as elaborated below. What is
relevant here is that this intertwining of low employment generation and
increasing poverty has been an important feature of the experience of
the last decade and more so in Pakistan.
Bangladesh
Much
like other countries in the region, Bangladesh also adopted the standard
range of neo-liberal economic reforms beginning in the 1980s and much
more comprehensively in the 1990s. These included the usual combination
of expenditure-reducing and expenditure-switching policies, along with
institutional and legislative changes aimed at ensuring greater freedom
of market functioning.
The results of this strategy appear to have been mixed. There was
clearly greater macroeconomic stability in terms of reduced rates of
inflation (from an average of 9.9. per cent per annum in the early 1980s
to an average of 5.6 per cent per annum by the end of the 1990s).
However, the trend rate of growth of GDP in constant prices appears to
have been remarkably stable, at around 4 per cent, suggesting that the
reforms package had very little effect on the trend rate of growth.
Also, trends in the fiscal deficit (as share of GDP) appear to have been
substantially post reform, in the 1990s, compared to the 1980s. This
also reflects the decline in tax revenues consequent upon fiscal reforms
and trade liberalization.
Muqtada (2003, page 8) has concluded that 'stabilization and the SAPs,
to the extent implemented, do not seem to have produced any perceptible
growth dividends'. It is notable that while the supposed 'fundamentals'
of the economy have improved, these have failed to increase rates of
investment and growth. However, growth rates per capita do show
significant increase, mainly because of the demographic transition
involving declines in rates of population growth (from 2.1 per cent in
1990 to only 1.6 per cent in 2000).
The most recent Labour Force Survey suggests that employment growth grew
at around 3 per cent per annum in the period 1995–2000. While this is
still below the rate of increase of the labour force (estimated to be
3.4 per cent by the same survey) it is higher than in the earlier
period.
However, there are doubts about how and in which sectors such a jump in
employment occurred. While the new export sector of readymade garments
has provided an important source of new employment (especially for
women) total employment in aggregate manufacturing has actually
declined, in both relative and absolute terms.
There has been significant de-industrialization, particularly in the
traditional sectors that have suffered from import penetration. Open
unemployment has risen from 1.8 per cent of the labour force to 4.9 per
cent, while underemployment in 2000 was estimated to be very high at
around 31 per cent.
What
is more remarkable in the case of Bangladesh is the fact that changes in
the structure of output of the economy have been completely different
from changes in the sectoral composition of employment. These are shown
in Chart 6 and Chart 7.
It is
apparent from these charts that while the GDP share of agriculture fell
by nearly half, its share of employment actually increased, contrary to
the standard expectation with respect to the process of development.
Indeed, the distribution of employment reflects hardly any structural
change in the economy, while the composition of GDP indicates a more
usual process of declining agriculture and increasing industry, albeit
with a very large role played by services.
Average productivity in agriculture remains low and wages in that sector
have been lower than in manufacturing, with the gap widening. Therefore
agriculture is clearly a residual sector in the context of Bangladesh,
absorbing labour that cannot obtain productive employment elsewhere. It
is possible that services have been playing a similar role.
The poor employment generation in the manufacturing sector reflects a
combination of declines in the traditional manufacturing sectors and
(given the rising share of aggregate output) increases in labour
productivity which are the result of sectoral shifts and changing
technology. The latter tends to be confirmed by the rising real wages in
manufacturing. This conforms to the pattern we have already observed in
other countries of South Asia, where the competitive pressures resulting
from greater openness have involved technological changes which are on
the whole labour-displacing.
Poverty is estimated to have declined in the latter part of the 1990s,
although the rural incidence remains high at around 30 per cent of the
rural population.
There is a common perception that the micro-credit delivery systems in
Bangladesh has operated to provide a cushion for poor households in case
of shocks such as crop failures, floods and other natural disasters. It
has also helped to improve the relative position of women. However, the
features of micro-credit (short-term, relatively small amounts, groups
lending pressure for prompt repayment) mean that it has not contributed
much to asset creation among the poor or to sustained employment
generation. (Centre for Policy Dialogue 2001)
The
expansion of public transport infrastructure, especially road- networks
in the 1980s, may have contributed to subsequent rural development which
in turn assisted the reduction of poverty in that later period. However,
trade liberalization had the counter effect of reducing the viability of
many small producers, so the net effect of all the policy changes over
the period is not clear.
It is likely that some of the effects of openness were adverse for
livelihood and therefore it led to poverty, and these were to some
extent mitigated by the spread of public transport networks and the
availability of micro-credit.
Sri Lanka
At
first glance, Sri Lanka apparently shows reasonably good economic growth
and employment generation performance from the early 1990s. This is
somewhat surprising, since the country was among the least stable due to
the intensification of internal conflict, and has also undergone similar
policies of neoliberal adjustment and privatization from the 1980s
onwards.
The country had to suffer major violent conflicts over the last decade,
amounting at times to a civil war, especially in the northern
Tamil-dominated region. This not only meant the destruction of many
lives and of physical and social infrastructure, but also created
uncertain conditions for private investment and involved massive
increases in military spending by the government.
In fact the growth of the Sri Lankan economy-at an average of more than
5 per cent per annum over the 1990s-exhibited substantial volatility and
there are also doubts about its sustainability, because of the large
build-up of public debt it has been associated with. By the turn of the
decade the fragile nature of the growth process and the increased
external vulnerability of the Sri Lankan economy were exposed, when
there was a mini balance-of-payments crisis, resulting from a temporary
decline in aid inflows and export receipts. In 2001, GDP fell by 1.3 per
cent.
Sri Lanka underwent neo-liberal economic reform packages similar to
those of other countries in South Asia, but from an even earlier period,
starting in the late 1970s. The process was marked in the 1980s with the
replacement of a universal system of food distribution with targeted
food stamps and other changes deigned to reduce the welfare
redistributive schemes of the state, and continued with an intensified
programme of fiscal retrenchment and privatization of state assets,
including plantations, from the early 1990s.
The economic
policies adopted during the last two decades were oriented towards
accelerating 'growth' through liberalization, export orientation and
privatization, with the assumption that growth would trickle down and
reduce poverty. However, even the World Bank, which was actively
associated with promoting these policies, now admits that neither
adequate growth nor poverty reduction have been achieved during this
period (World Bank 2002: 10).
While the rate of growth of output increased in the 1990s, it is
noteworthy that it was associated with lower rates of employment
expansion than the previous two decades that were characterized by lower
rates of aggregate GDP growth (Chart 8). This is precisely the same
pattern we have already observed in Pakistan, and to a lesser extent in
India.
In
terms of structural change, the Sri Lankan economy experienced what
would be considered as the 'standard' process of relative decline in the
share of the primary sector. However, the share of the secondary sector
was broadly stable over the last two decades after declining in the
1970s, and services now account for more than half of GDP
.
(Chart 9)
In
fact, there is more to this structural change than is immediately
apparent, since it is the result of a significantly changing profile in
agriculture, with a steady decline in the traditional export crops. The
share of such crops (tea, rubber and coconut) declined from 34 per cent
of value added in agriculture in 1980 to only 20 per cent in 1999. Even
rice, the mainstay of traditional agriculture, declined from 27 per cent
of value added in agriculture to 18 per cent over the same period, as a
range of 'other crops' emerged to dominate. The decline in the
plantation crops was reflected in the declining share of the processing
of tea, rubber and coconut in total manufacturing, from 34 per cent to
15 per cent, and a corresponding rise in the share of factory industry.
This was also reflected in the changing composition of exports. The
share of agricultural exports declined from 62 per cent in 1980 to 21
per cent in 1999, while industrial exports increased from 33 per cent to
77 per cent.
However, these massive shifts in production structure are not reflected
in employment patterns: while the share of agriculture in total
employment declined from 42 per cent to 36 per cent, the share of
manufacturing employment remained absolutely stagnant at only 15 per
cent, between 1990 and 1999. As in other South Asian countries, the
increase has been in services employment, which is likely to have been
operating as the residual or refuge sector once again.
It is true that open unemployment rates have declined substantially. But
this is likely to reflect more of the discouraged-worker effect than an
actual increase in job availability, given the deceleration in
employment expansion that was already noted.
Further, as the Government of Sri Lanka has also noted (2002: 4) 'Among
the so-called "employed" are people that have worked for as little as
one hour per week in paid employment. This definition hides many who are
significantly under-employed and who are in need of full-time productive
jobs. (It has been estimated that the number of "under-employed" amount
to as many as 20 per cent of the total workforce, or approximately 1.3
million people.) Also included as "employed" are approximately 673,000
people that are classified as "unpaid family workers", many of who would
no doubt welcome full-time, paid work if it were available."
The
official estimates for Sri Lanka suggest fluctuations and no downward
trend in the incidence of poverty by the head count ratio (Chart 10).
Further, there is substantial difference across the regions: if the more
prosperous western region was excluded, aggregate poverty figures would
be much higher, since it is in the range of 41–55 per cent for all the
other provinces, according to the higher poverty line. Poverty incidence
is highest in the estate sector, at 45 per cent, and lowest in urban Sri
Lanka at 25 per cent but in all of these categories, it has stubbornly
persisted at its earlier levels despite the more-than-5 per cent growth
of the economy.
There
is little doubt that this persistence of poverty is related not only to
various measures taken by the government which have reduced access to
basic needs and public goods over the period from the mid-1980s, but
also because the process of liberalization and privatization thus far
has simply not generated enough productive employment.
Conclusion
Given
the patterns observed above, it is not surprising that increasing
employment generation is now the explicit concern in recent planning and
policy documents in all of these countries, even India. It is strange
however, that while the explicit goal has changed from growth in itself
to employment generation, the strategies that are supposed to achieve
this essentially involve further doses of neo-liberal marketist reform,
rather than policies that would directly affect employment.
Thus, most of the policy statements refer to further privatization,
further deregulation of domestic economic activity, further financial
liberalization and external capital account liberalization, and further
restrictions on fiscal policies. These are precisely the set of policies
that, as observed already, have been associated with deceleration of
employment in the last decade.
If employment generation is to be the focus of the new policy thrust in
the region, then it would actually require a rethinking of these
policies, towards more active state intervention in terms of supporting
employment-intensive activities through a range of trade, fiscal and
financial measures. Without such active involvement, aggregate
employment in the region is likely to continue to stagnate, and may even
deteriorate with further doses of neoliberal reform.