As far as developing countries are concerned, a WTO
secretariat paper published in 2000 asserts that the agricultural
exports of developing countries have expanded more
rapidly than those of the developed countries in the
post WTO period. However, data presented in the paper
show that the share of developing countries in global
agricultural exports has increased by only 1 percent
during the period of 1994 to 1998 (Table 3). This
minimal increase should be viewed against the fact
that more than 75 percent of WTO Member countries
are from the developing world and foreign trade in
a large number of developing countries is dominated
by agricultural products. And yet, these countries
together account for less than 50 percent of the global
agricultural trade and even after 5 years of implementation
of the Agreement on Agriculture the situation remains
virtually unchanged for them. Secondly, the paper
also mentions ''developing countries' import markets
(and in some cases transition economies) are becoming
increasingly important as outlets for agricultural
exports from developing countries''. This, on one
hand shows that developing countries are progressively
opening up their agricultural sector but on the other
hand, it also implies that the Agreement on Agriculture
has not yet helped developing countries to gain increased
market access in developed countries.
Table
3
>> Click
to Enlarge
It is widely accepted that three sets of actors account
for this failure of the AoA. The first, is that in
order to push through an agreement when there were
signs that the Uruguay Round was faltering, the liberalisation
of agricultural trade in the developed countries was
not pushed far enough. Second, is the ability to use
''loopholes'', especially those in the form of inadequately
well-defined Green and Blue Box measures, in the AoA,
to continue to support and protect farmers on the
grounds that such support was non-trade distorting.
Finally, there are violations of even the lax UR rules
in the course of implementation, which have been aided
by the failure of the agreement to ensure transparency
in implementation.
Not surprisingly, some countries, especially the Cairns
group of exporting countries have proposed an ambitious
agenda of liberalisation in the agricultural area.
Tariffs are to be reduced sharply, using the ''Swiss
formula'', which would ensure that the proportionate
reduction in the tariffs imposed by a country would
be larger, the higher is the prevailing bound or applied
tariff in that country. The formula arrives at the
level to which tariffs in a country would be reduced
by multiplying the existing (bound or applied) tariff
by a numerical factor, and dividing the result by
the sum of the current tariff rate and the numerical
factor. The factor for developed countries proposed
by the Cairns group is 25. Thus, a country with a
tariff rate of 100 per cent on a particular product
would have to reduce the rate to 20 per cent (2500/125),
whereas a country with a 75 per cent tariff rate would
have to reduce it proportionately less to 18.75 per
cent (1875/100). Further, in keeping with the Special
and Differential treatment requirement, the factor
for the developing countries is proposed at 50, making
their reduction requirements much smaller (to 33.3
and 30 per cent respectively in the case of a 100
and 75 per cent tariff).
Besides tariff reduction, the Cairns group has called
for an enhancement of the minimum import levels of
particular commodities by using lower tariffs (tariff
rate quotas), argued for a sharp reduction in the
aggregate support that can be provided using impermissible
support measures, supported the scrapping of the so-called
Blue Box measures fashioned during the Uruguay Round
to appease the EU countries, and recommended stricter
guidelines for assessing whether particular measures
of support fall under fully permissible Green Box
provisions.
These ambitious demands notwithstanding, it is clear
that an agreement on modalities in time for the March
31 deadline is unlikely to materialise. Around the
time of the January 22-24 meetings of the agricultural
negotiators, the European Union Agricultural Commissioner
Franz Fischler made it clear that that the late March
deadline will be missed. Fischler reportedly declared
that the March 31 deadline set at Doha was for the
chairman of the agricultural negotiating group to
present his proposal for modalities and that did ''not
mean automatically that the next day all members of
the WTO will agree to that proposal.'' In any case,
with discussions on the reform of the EU's Common
Agricultural Policy expected to continue well into
the summer, the EC does not yet have a fully formulated
position to adopt in the course of the negotiations.
Thus, the March 31 deadline cannot be met.
Till such time as these issues are cleared it is not
at all certain that an agreement on agriculture, which
is a prerequisite for the launch and completion of
the 'Doha Round' of trade negotiations, can be ensured
by 2005. Those in a hurry to get to that goal are
in for a disappointment. But that prospect is not
new. WTO members have already missed a December deadline
for an agreement on patents and the supply of essential
commodities, because of US intransigence. They have
also missed the deadline to work out modalities for
special and differential treatment of developing countries.
In the media's blame game seeking to identify the
culprit holding up progress towards an agreement on
agriculture, once again the lead contender is the
European Union. The grounds for this focus on the
EU are, however, shaky. The United States too offers
substantial support to its farmers, and has significantly
hiked this support through the Farm Security and Rural
Investment Act of 2002. Outlays on farm programmes
in the US, principally income and price support programmes,
averaged more than $15 billion a year between 1996
and 2002, and had touched a high of $32.3 billion
in 2000. The 2002 Act promises on paper to keep this
high support going, by authorising expenditures totalling
$118.5 billion over a six-year period ending 2007.
The actual figure is expected to be much higher. It
is well known that this support goes disproportionately
in favour of a few large commercial farms, which are
the ones accounting for a majority of supplies to
the US and international markets.
In as much as such support, even if provided in the
form of direct income payments ''decoupled" from
actual production, indirectly affects farmers' production
and pricing decisions, they influence availability
and prices in world markets. That is they do distort
world trade, even if the UR round agreement claims
they do not. What the 2002 Farm Act indicates is that
the US has no intention of cutting back on such support,
and is unlikely to accede to any agreement that warrants
such a cut. The reason why this implicit stance of
the US does not lead to its identification as a bottleneck
in the current negotiations on agriculture is that
almost all of this support is in the form of Green
Box measures, or measures of support that are acceptable
under the Uruguay Round agreement because they are
ostensibly ''non-trade distorting".
Not surprisingly, the US proposals advanced in the
course of the work programme that began in March 2002,
combine (i) a plea for export subsidy abolition; (ii)
recommendations for increased market access through
quota abolition, tariff reduction and enhanced tariff-rate
quotas (or a minimum level of imports of each commodity
that needs to be ensured with lower tariffs); and
(iii) a case for either doing away with domestic support
that does not fall in the Green Box category or the
substitution of such support with outlays on new Green
Box measures. That is the US proposals are clearly
not in the direction of reducing state support for
agriculture, but of manipulating the agricultural
support regime in the direction of what was defined
to be non-trade distorting in the course of the Uruguay
Round.
Seen in this background the new stand on agricultural
support still being discussed among EU members is
by no means bizarre. The European Commission's recently
released proposals for reform of the Common Agricultural
Policy (CAP) do not promise any cut in total spending.
But they do not point to any substantial increase
either, since the EU leaders agreed last year to a
1 per cent ceiling on annual increases in the farm
budget. In addition, the proposals currently being
discussed make an effort to link subsidies less directly
with production, thereby rendering them non-trade
distorting.
The difficulty the EU faces is that of mooting and
then winning agreement among its members on doing
away with export subsidies and on making a complete
transition to Green Box measures. Since the support
afforded to agriculture in EU countries is large and
multifarious, a complete transition is not easy to
achieve. France, for example, which receives more
money from the CAP than any other country is vehemently
opposed to that transition, with vocal support from
President Chirac. As a result the EU in its proposals
submitted in December to the agricultural negotiations
committee has called for retaining the Blue Box and
for continuing with the Peace Clause, which protected
Blue Box measures from being challenged during the
implementation period of the Uruguay Round. That is
the EU wants the right to openly and transparently
support and protect its farmers, and wants adequate
elbowroom within the agreement to do so. But the fact
that it is unwilling to go the US way, by opting for
less transparent support measures that have been defined
as acceptable helps those who paint it as the stumbling
block on the road to free trade.
The reason for the peculiar situation is that through
the manoeuvres made during the Uruguay Round, especially
the famous Blair House accord, the rich nations managed
to obtain Cairns group concurrence and developing
country support for an agreement that provided inadequate
market access and little reduction in protection in
the developed countries in the agricultural area.
This they did by holding out the threat of trade chaos
if no agreement was reached and by promising (i) that
this was an interim arrangement which would be assessed
starting a year before the completion of the implementation
period; (ii) that the worst form of domestic support
such as the blue box measures would be dropped at
that point; and (iii) liberalisation would be further
intensified starting in 2000.
Unfortunately, not only has the experience with the
implementation of the not-so-liberal Uruguay Round
Agreement on Agriculture been wanting on many counts,
but there is strong pressure to continue with the
manoeuvring by dressing up all support measures in
Green, as is the case with the US, or by just refusing
to meet the Uruguay Round commitments, as is true
of the EU. This makes it extremely difficult to once
more win Cairns group concurrence and developing country
support for a new Agreement on Agriculture, which
offers merely a small advance along an older protectionist
route.
Unfortunately for the developed countries they had
gone for the ''single undertaking'', all-or-nothing
strategy with the hope that they can use small concessions
in areas like agriculture, drug patents and Special
and Differential treatment to win major battles in
the areas of competition policy, foreign investment
and public procurement. But with no agreement among
them even on those concessions and an agreement on
agriculture proving a stumbling block, those visions
born of greed are threatening to blur. The threat
to the forces of corporate globalisation comes not
just from the anti-globalisation movement outside.
An important enemy seems to lie within, as well.