At
the end of the latest round of meetings of the agricultural negotiations
committee of the WTO, the optimism that negotiators would meet the March
31 deadline for working out numerical targets, formulas and other
“modalities" through which countries can frame their liberalisation
commitments in a new full-fledged round of trade negotiations has almost
disappeared. That target was important for two reasons. First, it is now
becoming clear, that even more than was true during the Uruguay Round,
forging an agreement in the agricultural area is bound to prove
extremely difficult. Progress in the agricultural negotiations was key
to persuading the unconvinced that a new 'Doha Round' of trade
negotiations is useful and feasible.
Second, the Doha declaration made agricultural negotiations one part of
a 'single undertaking' to be completed by January 1, 2005. That is, in a
take 'all-or-nothing' scheme, countries had to arrive at and be bound by
agreements in all areas in which negotiations were to be initiated in
the new round. This means that if agreement is not worked out with
regard to agriculture, there would be no change in the multilateral
trade regime governing industry, services or related areas and no
progress in new areas, such as competition policy, foreign investment
and public procurement, all of which are crucial to the economic agenda
of the developed countries.
The factors making agriculture the sticking point on this occasion are
numerous. As in the last Round, there is little agreement among the
developed countries themselves on the appropriate shape of the global
agricultural trade regime. There are substantial differences in the
agenda of the US, the EU and the developed countries within the Cairns
group of agricultural exporters. When the rich and the powerful
disagree, a global consensus is not easy to come by.
In this round of negotiation, the complexity of the situation is likely
to increase because a number of developing country including Cuba,
Chile, Kenya, India, Nigeria, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Uganda and Zimbabwe
has taken a very pro-active role in the negotiations and have often
expressed vies which are significantly different from the views
expressed by the big three. The extent of disagreement among different
country groups can be gauged from a recent paper by the Chairman of WTO
Agriculture Committee Stuart Harbinson. This paper is based on the
country proposals submitted during the current round of agricultural
negations and the follow up consultations among the WTO Members
conducted after Doha ministerial. The objective of this paper is to
summarize the main features and results of the consultations and to
provide a basis for working towards the establishment of modalities for
the further commitments. This paper shows that not only there are still
wide gaps in the positions among participants regarding fundamental
aspects of the further negotiations but there also exist significant
differences in the level of ambition among the member countries. What is
even more worrying for the future of the agricultural negotiation is
that even the latest round of talks, countries are not showing any
inclination towards reconciliation. According to reports published in
the International Trade Daily, after a negotiating group session held
during 22-24th January 2003, Harbinson noted that the meeting was
intended to "build bridges" between opposing camps and push the WTO
talks forward as members head towards their March 31 deadline for
finalizing negotiating modalities. Instead, he adds, "we have made very
little headway in building bridges".
It is expected that with members failing to mend their differences, the
first draft of a methodology framework for agricultural negotiations
will be chair driven and is expected to be circulated before a
mini-Ministerial scheduled for Tokyo Feb. 14-16. Given the progress so
far, it seems virtually impossible that the March 31st deadline of
finalizing the modalities will be met.
But that is not all. Even if an agreement is stitched up between the
rich nations, through manoeuvres such as the Blair House accord, getting
the rest of the world to go along would be more difficult this time.
This is because the outcomes in the agricultural trade area since the
implementation of the Uruguay Round (UR) Agreement on Agriculture (AoA)
began have fallen far short of expectations. In the course of Round,
advocates of the UR regime had promised global production adjustments
that would increase the value of world agricultural trade and an
increase in developing country share of such trade.
As Chart 1 shows, global production volumes continued to rise after 1994
when the implementation of the Uruguay Round began, with signs of
tapering off only in 2000 and 2001. As is widely known, this increase in
production occurred in the developed countries as well.
Not surprisingly, therefore, the volume of world trade continued to rise
after 1994 (Chart 2). The real shift occurred in agricultural prices
which, after some buoyancy between 1993 and 1995, have declined
thereafter, and particularly sharply after 1997. It is this decline in
unit values that resulted in a situation where the value of world trade
stagnated and then declined after 1995, when the implementation of the
Uruguay Round began.
As Table 1 shows, there was a sharp fall in the rate of growth of global
agricultural trade between the second half of the 1980s and the 1990s,
with the decline in growth in the 1990s being due to the particularly
poor performance during the 1998 to 2001 period.
Price declines and stagnation in agricultural trade values in the wake
of the UR Agreement on Agriculture were accompanied and partly
influenced by the persisting regionalisation of world agricultural
trade. The foci of such regionalisation were Western Europe and Asia,
with 32 and 11 per cent of global agricultural trade being intra-Western
European and intra-Asian trade respectively (Chart 3). What is
noteworthy, however, is that agricultural exports accounted for a much
higher share of both merchandise and primary products trade in North
America and Western Europe (besides Latin America and Africa) then it
did for Asia. Thus despite being the developed regions of the world,
agricultural production and exports were important influences on the
economic performance of North America and Western Europe.
It is therefore not surprising that Europe is keen on maintaining its
agricultural sector through protection, while the US is keen on
expanding its role in world agricultural markets by subsidising its own
farmers and forcing other countries to open up their markets. The
problem is that the US has been more successful in prising open
developing country markets than the large EU market. Thus out of $104
billion worth of exports from North America in 2001, $34 billion went to
Asia and $15 billion to Latin America, whereas exports to Europe
amounted to $14 billion (Table 2).
The Cairns group of exporting countries (Argentina, Australia, Bolivia,
Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Guatemala, Indonesia,
Malaysia, New Zealand, Paraguay, Philippines, South Africa, Thailand and
Uruguay), for some of who at least agricultural exports are extremely
important, want world market to be freed of protection as well as
the surpluses that result from huge domestic support in the US and the
EC. We must note that $35 billion of the $63 billion of exports from
Latin America went to the US and the EU. More open markets and less
domestic support in those destinations is therefore crucial for the
region.
The fact that Europe has been successful in its effort at retaining its
agricultural space with the help of a Common Agricultural Policy that
both supports and subsidises its agricultural producers is clear from
Chart 4, which shows that intra-EC trade which accounted for 74 per cent
of EU exports in 1990, continued to account for 73 per cent of total EU
exports in 1995 and 2001. But North America, with far fewer countries in
its fold, has also been quite insular. Close to a third of North
American exports are intra-regional. Little has changed since the
Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture.
As far as developing countries are concerned, a WTO secretariat paper
published in 2000
asserts that the agricultural exports of developing countries have
expanded more rapidly than those of the developed countries in the post
WTO period. However, data presented in the paper show that the share of
developing countries in global agricultural exports has increased by
only 1 percent during the period of 1994 to 1998 (Table 3). This minimal
increase should be viewed against the fact that more than 75 percent of
WTO Member countries are from the developing world and foreign trade in
a large number of developing countries is dominated by agricultural
products. And yet, these countries together account for less than 50
percent of the global agricultural trade and even after 5 years of
implementation of the Agreement on Agriculture the situation remains
virtually unchanged for them. Secondly, the paper also mentions
“developing countries' import markets (and in some cases transition
economies) are becoming increasingly important as outlets for
agricultural exports from developing countries”. This, on one hand
shows that developing countries are progressively opening up their
agricultural sector but on the other hand, it also implies that the
Agreement on Agriculture has not yet helped developing countries to gain
increased market access in developed countries.
It is widely accepted that three sets of actors account for this failure
of the AoA. The first, is that in order to push through an agreement
when there were signs that the Uruguay Round was faltering, the
liberalisation of agricultural trade in the developed countries was not
pushed far enough. Second, is the ability to use “loopholes”, especially
those in the form of inadequately well-defined Green and Blue Box
measures, in the AoA, to continue to support and protect farmers on the
grounds that such support was non-trade distorting. Finally, there are
violations of even the lax UR rules in the course of implementation,
which have been aided by the failure of the agreement to ensure
transparency in implementation.
Not surprisingly, some countries, especially the Cairns group of
exporting countries have proposed an ambitious agenda of liberalisation
in the agricultural area. Tariffs are to be reduced sharply, using the
“Swiss formula”, which would ensure that the proportionate reduction in
the tariffs imposed by a country would be larger, the higher is the
prevailing bound or applied tariff in that country. The formula arrives
at the level to which tariffs in a country would be reduced by
multiplying the existing (bound or applied) tariff by a numerical
factor, and dividing the result by the sum of the current tariff rate
and the numerical factor. The factor for developed countries proposed by
the Cairns group is 25. Thus, a country with a tariff rate of 100 per
cent on a particular product would have to reduce the rate to 20 per
cent (2500/125), whereas a country with a 75 per cent tariff rate would
have to reduce it proportionately less to 18.75 per cent (1875/100).
Further, in keeping with the Special and Differential treatment
requirement, the factor for the developing countries is proposed at 50,
making their reduction requirements much smaller (to 33.3 and 30 per
cent respectively in the case of a 100 and 75 per cent tariff).
Besides tariff reduction, the Cairns group has called for an enhancement
of the minimum import levels of particular commodities by using lower
tariffs (tariff rate quotas), argued for a sharp reduction in the
aggregate support that can be provided using impermissible support
measures, supported the scrapping of the so-called Blue Box measures
fashioned during the Uruguay Round to appease the EU countries, and
recommended stricter guidelines for assessing whether particular
measures of support fall under fully permissible Green Box provisions.
These ambitious demands notwithstanding, it is clear that an agreement
on modalities in time for the March 31 deadline is unlikely to
materialise. Around the time of the January 22-24 meetings of the
agricultural negotiators, the European Union Agricultural Commissioner
Franz Fischler made it clear that that the late March deadline will be
missed. Fischler reportedly declared that the March 31 deadline set at
Doha was for the chairman of the agricultural negotiating group to
present his proposal for modalities and that did “not mean automatically
that the next day all members of the WTO will agree to that proposal.”
In any case, with discussions on the reform of the EU's Common
Agricultural Policy expected to continue well into the summer, the EC
does not yet have a fully formulated position to adopt in the course of
the negotiations. Thus, the March 31 deadline cannot be met.
Till such time as these issues are cleared it is not at all certain that
an agreement on agriculture, which is a prerequisite for the launch and
completion of the 'Doha Round' of trade negotiations, can be ensured by
2005. Those in a hurry to get to that goal are in for a disappointment.
But that prospect is not new. WTO members have already missed a December
deadline for an agreement on patents and the supply of essential
commodities, because of US intransigence. They have also missed the
deadline to work out modalities for special and differential treatment
of developing countries.
In the media's blame game seeking to identify the culprit holding up
progress towards an agreement on agriculture, once again the lead
contender is the European Union. The grounds for this focus on the EU
are, however, shaky. The United States too offers substantial support to
its farmers, and has significantly hiked this support through the Farm
Security and Rural Investment Act of 2002. Outlays on farm programmes in
the US, principally income and price support programmes, averaged more
than $15 billion a year between 1996 and 2002, and had touched a high of
$32.3 billion in 2000. The 2002 Act promises on paper to keep this high
support going, by authorising expenditures totalling $118.5 billion over
a six-year period ending 2007. The actual figure is expected to be much
higher. It is well known that this support goes disproportionately in
favour of a few large commercial farms, which are the ones accounting
for a majority of supplies to the US and international markets.
In as much as such support, even if provided in the form of direct
income payments “decoupled" from actual production, indirectly affects
farmers' production and pricing decisions, they influence availability
and prices in world markets. That is they do distort world trade, even
if the UR round agreement claims they do not. What the 2002 Farm Act
indicates is that the US has no intention of cutting back on such
support, and is unlikely to accede to any agreement that warrants such a
cut. The reason why this implicit stance of the US does not lead to its
identification as a bottleneck in the current negotiations on
agriculture is that almost all of this support is in the form of Green
Box measures, or measures of support that are acceptable under the
Uruguay Round agreement because they are ostensibly “non-trade
distorting".
Not surprisingly, the US proposals advanced in the course of the work
programme that began in March 2002, combine (i) a plea for export
subsidy abolition; (ii) recommendations for increased market access
through quota abolition, tariff reduction and enhanced tariff-rate
quotas (or a minimum level of imports of each commodity that needs to be
ensured with lower tariffs); and (iii) a case for either doing away with
domestic support that does not fall in the Green Box category or the
substitution of such support with outlays on new Green Box measures.
That is the US proposals are clearly not in the direction of reducing
state support for agriculture, but of manipulating the agricultural
support regime in the direction of what was defined to be non-trade
distorting in the course of the Uruguay Round.
Seen in this background the new stand on agricultural support still
being discussed among EU members is by no means bizarre. The European
Commission's recently released proposals for reform of the Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP) do not promise any cut in total spending. But
they do not point to any substantial increase either, since the EU
leaders agreed last year to a 1 per cent ceiling on annual increases in
the farm budget. In addition, the proposals currently being discussed
make an effort to link subsidies less directly with production, thereby
rendering them non-trade distorting.
The difficulty the EU faces is that of mooting and then winning
agreement among its members on doing away with export subsidies and on
making a complete transition to Green Box measures. Since the support
afforded to agriculture in EU countries is large and multifarious, a
complete transition is not easy to achieve. France, for example, which
receives more money from the CAP than any other country is vehemently
opposed to that transition, with vocal support from President Chirac. As
a result the EU in its proposals submitted in December to the
agricultural negotiations committee has called for retaining the Blue
Box and for continuing with the Peace Clause, which protected Blue Box
measures from being challenged during the implementation period of the
Uruguay Round. That is the EU wants the right to openly and
transparently support and protect its farmers, and wants adequate
elbowroom within the agreement to do so. But the fact that it is
unwilling to go the US way, by opting for less transparent support
measures that have been defined as acceptable helps those who paint it
as the stumbling block on the road to free trade.
The reason for the peculiar situation is that through the manoeuvres
made during the Uruguay Round, especially the famous Blair House accord,
the rich nations managed to obtain Cairns group concurrence and
developing country support for an agreement that provided inadequate
market access and little reduction in protection in the developed
countries in the agricultural area. This they did by holding out the
threat of trade chaos if no agreement was reached and by promising (i)
that this was an interim arrangement which would be assessed starting a
year before the completion of the implementation period; (ii) that the
worst form of domestic support such as the blue box measures would be
dropped at that point; and (iii) liberalisation would be further
intensified starting in 2000.
Unfortunately, not only has the experience with the implementation of
the not-so-liberal Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture been wanting
on many counts, but there is strong pressure to continue with the
manoeuvring by dressing up all support measures in Green, as is the case
with the US, or by just refusing to meet the Uruguay Round commitments,
as is true of the EU. This makes it extremely difficult to once more win
Cairns group concurrence and developing country support for a new
Agreement on Agriculture, which offers merely a small advance along an
older protectionist route.
Unfortunately for the developed countries they had gone for the “single
undertaking”, all-or-nothing strategy with the hope that they can use
small concessions in areas like agriculture, drug patents and Special
and Differential treatment to win major battles in the areas of
competition policy, foreign investment and public procurement. But with
no agreement among them even on those concessions and an agreement on
agriculture proving a stumbling block, those visions born of greed are
threatening to blur. The threat to the forces of corporate globalisation
comes not just from the anti-globalisation movement outside. An
important enemy seems to lie within, as well.