The
premise underlying the report of the Committee is that the fiscal deficit
is the key parameter affecting all other macro-economic and growth variables,
and that its control is absolutely necessary for the realisation of
all economic objectives of the government. "To sustain and accelerate
the high growth, to maintain inflation at a low level, to avoid vulnerability
on the external balance of payments front and to nurture the growth
of a vibrant financial sector including the banking system, it is absolutely
imperative to reverse the current fiscal stance towards greater fiscal
rectitude." (Report, page 5) In addition, fiscal consolidation
is seen as necessary to lower interest rates and therefore to encourage
higher private investment.
Such
an axiomatic understanding is not one that can be justified either by
newer theoretical work or by recent international experience, which
actually point to very different causal relationships. Let us consider
each of these explicit assumptions in turn.
First
is the argument that lower fiscal deficits lead to higher and more sustained
growth. This need not be the case on either theoretical or empirical
grounds. If the deficit is dominantly in the form of capital expenditure,
it contributes to future growth through demand and supply linkages.
Also, since there is a strong positive correlation between public and
private investment, which is now accepted even by institutions like
the World Bank, more such public spending would stimulate more overall
investment and thus growth. The "crowding in " effects of
public investment are now generally acknowledged to dominate over "crowding
out" effects in developing countries in particular.
Indeed,
the deflationary effect of lower fiscal deficits is one that is widely
and openly recognised by most governments even in Europe, although they
may be forced to try and curtail their deficits because of other reasons
such as financial sector pressure. So, both in the short term, where
there is an immediately obvious trade-off between a lower fiscal deficit
and higher growth, and in the medium term, reducing deficits may well
have depressing effects on economic activity.
Second,
it is wrong to argue that large fiscal deficits necessarily lead to
higher inflation. Inflation is caused by the excess of aggregate expenditure
over aggregate income, which may come from public or private sectors,
and is reflected in either inflation or current account deficits in
the balance of payments. It is quite possible for a large public deficit
to be entirely financed by a private sector savings surplus, as was
the case in Italy for more than a decade, where fiscal deficits of as
much as 9 per cent of GDP were met by positive private savings-investment
balances of equal proportions. Similarly, there can be large balance
of payments deficits or higher inflation in countries with low, zero
or positive fiscal accounts, when the private sector spends more than
it earns - this was the case in many Southeast Asian economies before
the crisis, and is currently true of the United States economy.
Third,
external vulnerability now has less to do with the observance of fiscal
rectitude, and more to do with the degree of financial openness of the
economy as well as a range of perceptions of international finance.
Thus, countries can face external crisis and capital flight because
of large current account deficits led by private profligacy in the context
of trade and capital account liberalisation, or because other areas
are suddenly seen as more profitable by financial investors, or even
just because of geographical proximity to another country in crisis.
It
is important to remember that in 1997, when the financial crisis engulfed
Southeast Asia, among the two worst affected countries, Thailand had
a government budget surplus of 3 per cent of GDP while South Korea had
a smaller budget surplus of 1 per cent of GDP. Their current account
deficits reflected not fiscal irresponsibility but excess private spending
in the very liberalised environment desired by international finance.
In another part of the world, Argentina has faced speculative attacks
on its currency despite obsessive deficit control and even a fiscal
responsibility law, simply because of geographical proximity and an
open capital account, first during the Mexican crisis of 1995 and more
recently during the Brazilian crisis of 1998-99.
This
in turn means that the argument that fiscal rectitude is sufficient
to enable low interest rates in a world of relatively open capital markets,
is not one that can be sustained. In fact, while it is true that finance
in general dislikes large fiscal deficits, it is quite prepared to tolerate
them if they are associated with higher economic activity. Witness the
high state of "investor confidence" in South Korea currently,
even though the government deficit is now around 6 per cent of GDP,
because the expansionary fiscal stance is the main reason behind the
recovery in economic activity.
|