Even
this amount is just close to the levels of the recent
past, and below that of several years earlier. But the
extra 1.5 per cent of tax revenues on offer relates
to sales taxes on sugar, tobacco and textiles, and the
EFC has made it clear that those States which choose
to levy any tax on these items will not be allowed to
get any share of this. Since these are among those taxes
which do provide high revenues for several States, it
is quite likely that they may opt to continue to levy
such taxes, in which case they would no longer be eligible
for this additional amount.
In any case, it was hoped that the EFC would actually
increase the allocation of shared taxes to the States,
rather than simply continue along the lines of recent
experience which has clearly revealed the inadequacy
of the current devolution. Instead it has chosen what
for it was the softer option, of expecting the States
to raise a substantial amount of additional taxation,
on the implicit argument that the Central finances need
to be protected from further erosion. This leaves unsolved,
the critical problem of inadequate resources for the
wide range of development and infrastructure expenditure
which remains in the domain of State governments.
A further issue relates to the inter se distribution
of these resources among States. This is the area that
has received the most publicity in recent days, with
a number of State governments voicing their opposition
to the formula that has been presented by the EFC. It
is wrong to present the issue as a simple one of more
developed versus less developed States, or in regional
terms as South versus North.
It is true that a number of more developed southern
States are negatively affected in terms of a reduced
share of even the relatively small pool that is provided
to all the States. And some large northern States may
get more in proportionate terms, such as Uttar Pradesh
and Bihar. But there are various other States that also
appear to be "losers" in this respect, despite their
lack of development and relative poverty. These include
northeastern States like Assam, Manipur, Meghalaya and
Tripura. Interestingly, Jammu and Kashmir also comes
out as a relatively large loser.
The relevant point is not to consider which specific
states are gainers or losers but more generally to consider
the validity of the principles applied. And this is
where the EFC's recommendations certainly do appear
to be problematic. The pie diagrams in Chart 10 elaborate
on how the EFC's formula differs from the one used by
the Tenth Finance Commission.
Chart
10 >> Click
to Enlarge
There are several important differences. Firstly, the
weightage for population has been very sharply reduced,
from 20 per cent to only 10 per cent, which does seem
to contradict one basic principle of democracy. It is
true that the income criterion (which in this case is
the distance of the per capita income of a State from
the weighted average of the top three States) has been
increased, but only marginally from 60 per cent to 62.5
per cent. The weight for area has been increased from
5 per cent to 7.5 per cent, the reasons for which are
not entirely obvious. Similarly the weight for infrastructure
has also been increased.
But the most unjustified change of all comes in the
form of the introduction of a new element - that of
fiscal discipline. This has been given a weight of as
much as 7.5 per cent, and the weight of tax effort has
been halved from 10 per cent to 5 per cent accordingly.
This is both arbitrary and unfair, because it imposes
on all the state governments a certain conception of
fiscal viability which is part of the Central Government's
current approach, and reduces the reward for tax effort
which is a much more transparent and equitable consideration.
In any case, the idea of rewarding fiscal discipline
is extremely peculiar in the current context, because
such discipline can come about even as a result of mismanagement
whereby important expenditures necessary for welfare
and development are simply not made. The specific way
in which fiscal discipline is sought to be measured
is in terms of "the improvement in the ratio of own
revenue receipts of a State to its total revenue expenditure
related to a similar ratio for all States as a criterion
for measurement." The base year has been taken as the
average of 1990-91 to 1992-93, and the reference period
as the average of 1996-97 to 1998-99.
Note that the criterion is that of change rather than
absolute levels : thus if a state begins with better
fiscal balances but deteriorates slightly over this
period, it will come off worse than a state with much
worse overall balances which has experienced a slight
improvement. The average of all States which is taken
as reference for comparison also relates to rates of
change, so even in terms of applying some notion of
fiscal discipline this particular measure appears to
be flawed.
Note also that higher revenue receipts and lower revenue
expenditures are treated on par, which is a poor way
of dealing with situations in which States should ideally
be given incentives to increase those types of revenue
expenditure with clear positive welfare and growth effects.
In effect, the EFC seems to be subscribing to the idea,
commonplace among those less schooled in the economics
of public policy, that the smaller the economic role
of government, the better.
But the basic critique of using this - or indeed, any
notion of fiscal discipline - as a weight in determining
allocations to States is more fundamental. This is that
it uses an exogenous criterion which reflects only one
particular view of economic management, and does not
relate to the considerations which should normally work
in a democracy. The idea that this approach is "economic"
and not political in nature is completely wrong - once
again, as in the attitude to expenditure restraint,
it reflects a political choice whereby certain groups
in society are favoured over others.
Quite apart from the fact that it is ironic to observe
a Central government showing little or no "fiscal discipline"
itself, being given the power to allocate to States
according to this criterion, it is wrong to allow factors
like this to determine what is really a constitutionally
required need to devolve resources to different levels
of government. In fact, the very application of the
criterion of fiscal discipline goes against the basic
tenets of decentralisation, and is therefore in opposition
to greater fiscal federalism in itself.
It was pointed out at the beginning of this article
that greater federalism, and especially economic devolution,
is necessary in India today not only because it allows
for more democracy and greater accountability to citizens
than a more centralised system. It is also urgently
required because it may be a necessary condition for
the survival of our Union as stable polity able to provide
development to the people. That is really why the recommendations
of the EFC, which have failed to see the critical need
for much more devolution at this juncture, can be a
source of discontent. |