Although employment in general has been a major failure
of the macroeconomic policies of the past decade,
the decline in employment generation in agriculture
is probably more startling. The Census of India 2001
and the 55th Round of the NSS, both show
a dramatic slowdown (and in some states, actual decline)
of employment in agriculture.
The NSS data suggest that the employment elasticity
of agricultural output (the rate of change of employment
per unit change of GDP in agriculture) has fallen
from 0.7 in the period 1987–88 to 1993–94, to only
0.1 in the period 1993–94 to 1999–2000. This sharp
fall means that the employment elasticity is among
the lowest yet observed in Indian agriculture since
such data began to be collected.
Chart 1 gives some indication of the evidence from
the NSS. Employment growth rates are provided for
the periods 1987–88 to 1993–94 (hereafter the first
period) and 1993–94 to 1999–2000 (hereafter the second
period), using the 56th Round survey results
according to various definitions and superimposing
them on Census population figures. Note that these
reflect people employed rather than actual work, since
there is no real estimate of days/hours worked.
Chart
1 >>
Click
to Enlarge
The chart shows a very substantial decline of employment
by all indicators, to rates that are far below those
of growth of population over these periods. The usual
status definition, which refers to what a person usually
does over the year in question, can be interpreted
as a stock measure of employment. Both in terms of
principal activity and principal plus subsidiary activities,
there is evidence of very significant falls in employment
growth.
But there are even sharper falls, by the 'flows' definitions,
of weekly and daily status employment growth, suggesting
that even for those who saw themselves as usually
employed, there were difficulties in getting jobs
on a weekly or daily basis.
Furthermore, the data indicate that the sharpest fall
has been in the number of those classified as 'self-employed'
in agriculture, which has actually exhibited an absolute
overall decline. This means that the number of persons
working on household-operated holdings has gone down.
What explains this sharp fall in agricultural employment
growth? A wide range of explanations and associated
interpretations have been offered. A common explanation
hinges on the expansion of the non-agricultural sector
in rural areas. According to this argument, labour
has been moving out of agriculture in the standard
way predicted by the Lewis model, without affecting
productivity in agriculture because of the prevalence
of disguised unemployment in agriculture. This means
that the tendency is a wholly positive one, reflecting
acceleration of growth and development.
The problem with this argument is that while non-agricultural
employment has indeed increased as a share of population,
the increase is nowhere near enough to explain the
dramatic decline in agricultural employment generation.
In fact, both the increasing role of education for
the younger age cohort and the apparent increase in
non-agricultural employment growth, are inadequate
to counterbalance the sharply decelerating growth
in agricultural employment.
So much so that not all the increase in such employment
may be the result of positive pull factors. Rather,
several observers have described at least some of
the increased non-agricultural employment as possibly
reflecting a distress phenomenon (or 'push' process),
with rural residents desperately searching for any
jobs that are available or whatever can be described
as work.
Another explanation has to do with changes in technological
and cropping patterns that have reduced labour demand
in agriculture. These factors may certainly have played
an important role. Much of the more recent technological
change in Indian agriculture has taken the form of
mechanization that is labour-saving. Indeed, the rate
of labour-saving mechanization appears to have increased
over the past decade, and this has both reduced labour
demand and made smaller farmers relatively worse off.
Similarly, cropping-pattern changes are also likely
to have played a role because even while they can
have divergent effects, the general thrust of such
shifts (especially towards horticulture and floriculture
at the margin in some areas) may be said to have reduced
demand for labour.
An additional, and important, reason for the slowdown
in employment generation and the large fall in employment
elasticity of agricultural output growth may have
to do with the pattern of land relations in rural
India. It is now clear that this period witnessed
a significant degree of concentration in terms of
operated holdings, which reflected changes in both
ownership and tenancy patterns. Many small and very
marginal peasants lost their land during this period,
and have therefore been forced to look for work as
landless labourers; micro-level surveys have reported
increasing leasing-in by large farmers from small
landowners.
This is indicated, on an all-India level, in Chart
2. There has been a steep increase in landless households
as a percentage of total rural households, from around
35 per cent in 1987–88 to as much as 41 per cent in
1999–2000.
Chart
2 >>
Click
to Enlarge
It is well known that, for various reasons, persons
occupying small holdings tend to use land and labour
more intensively than those with larger farms, to
achieve higher per land unit productivity. Typically,
this means that they employ more household members
at least in some agricultural work, whether it be
principal or subsidiary activity. If those who previously
occupied land are now effectively dispossessed and
are forced to hire themselves out as wage labour,
the chances are low of a similar level of household
employment being achieved.