" It remains extremely difficult to determine to what extent these periodic reversals of capital flows have been themselves the cause of crises or a response to fundamental economic problems in the borrowing economies. Certainly such reversals have responded to excessive levels of debt, terms-of-trade shocks, or other events that reduce the prospects for economic growth in the borrowing countries. However, actions by creditor countries or lending institutions also have contributed. Crises have been sparked by monetary tightening in creditor countries and sudden changes in tolerance for risk on the part of lenders. Creditors have also contributed to crises by continuing to lend even in the face of evidence that funds were being directed to activities that could not generate sufficient returns with which to repay the debts created." (World Bank, Global Development Finance 2000, Washington, D. C., page 120).
 
On a similar note, the World Bank report is cautious about reacting to the possibility of a renewed spurt in capital flows to developing countries such as India, the prospect of which currently causes so much excitement among our own policy makers. Thus, while it recognises that the current pause in capital flows could last for some years, it also suggests that factors such as continued technological progress, rapid economic growth, a favourable political climate, and the ageing of industrial country populations (compared to the much younger age structure of most emerging markets) may well lead to a renewed boom in capital flows to emerging markets over the next decade.
 
The point, however, is that even such a renewed boom is not seen as necessarily a cause for celebration among the host emerging economies. Thus, the report argues that "if these inflows continue to be as volatile as they have been in the past, their benefits to the developing world may be reduced. Also, the spread of capital flows to countries with weak institutional capacity may increase the likelihood of crises in those economies. The great differences in incomes, legal and institutional frameworks, and cultural backgrounds between creditors and borrowers will tend to heighten the effects of asymmetric information and encourage herding among lenders. The growing role of banking systems in emerging markets in intermediating volatile capital flows could lead to greater risk to financial systems and could intensify the devastating effects of crises on economic output, particularly given the weakness of banking systems in many countries. Finally, continued financial innovation is likely to facilitate speculation and the rapid shifting of flows in and out of emerging markets." (page 120)
 
To counter these possible adverse consequences (note, of the boom in inflows as well, not just of the slump), the World Bank appears to have made a giant leap in its thinking in terms of recognising the relevance and viability of some capital controls. (Or could it just be the public swan song of the institution's departing Chief Economist, Joseph Stiglitz ?) Thus the report seriously considers a variety of capital control measures, ranging from taxation of short-term capital inflows to prudential controls on capital inflows, and also controls on capital outflows during crisis episodes along with liquidity-enhancing measures such as higher foreign currency reserves and contingent access to international credit. It allows that both the "market-friendly" prudential measures regulating inflows in Chile and the mid-crisis measures to control capital flight in Malaysia could have played important roles. But what is most important is that the report accepts that such controls need to be developed within countries according to specific requirements of particular economies.
 
Certainly the report recognises that such safeguards would impose costs on the domestic economy either by restricting the quantity of foreign borrowing or by raising its price. However, it quite sensibly points out that such costs are clearly likely to be less than the cost of a full-fledged financial crisis. What is even more significant is that finally the Bank also recognises the distributive element in such policy choices, since financial crises typically make the poor pay for the subsequent adjustment by bringing about fairly deep recessions which increase both unemployment and poverty. Regulations on capital flow, by contrast, tend to put a greater part of the adjustment on to those who actually benefit more directly from foreign borrowing.
 
All this is no more than a rather belated recognition (by an institution that is known for belated and partial responses) of the hard reality broadcast by the succession of financial crises that have hit emerging markets over the 1990s. But in the context of the currently ruling economic ideology in India, it appears not just heretical but impossible in terms of gaining official acceptance, if only because this echoes belatedly much of what Indian critics have written about the policies being followed in our country at the behest of the Bretton Woods institutions.
 
Obviously, the time will eventually come when these ideas are accepted generally by Indian policy makers and their economists as well. It remains to be seen whether this will simply follow the usual intellectual time-lag, or will be the result of bitter experience.

<< Previous Page | 1 | 2 |

 

Site optimised for 800 x 600 and above for Internet Explorer 5 and above
© MACROSCAN 2000