It is no secret that intellectual fashions in developing
countries, as indeed many other kinds of fashion, are often lagged versions
of what was earlier popular in the west. The mystery, then, is not that
such a tendency should exist in India as well. Rather, the questions
are why, even after the communications technology revolution, the time
lags in their adoption persist, and how such imported ideas can continue
to hold sway here well after they have been discredited elsewhere.
This is of course evident in all sorts of ways, whether in trends
in cinema and literature, or even in terms of choosing objects of adulation.
Thus, quite recently, much of the English language media in India expressed
a near-hysterical degree of obsequiousness in covering the visit of
Bill Clinton, a man who is already dismissed in his own country as a
somewhat embarrassing lame-duck President. Quite apart from the servility
reflected in a response which did not take into account the effects
for our own citizens of the policies symbolised by this man, it was
also an outdated reaction showing a retarded appreciation of current
reality.
But nowhere is this slowness in adapting modes of thought more sharply
illustrated than in terms of ideas about economic policy. The 1990s
was the decade of the explosion of free market ideology in economic
policy in the West, the period when dirigisme ran for cover and
government intervention of any variety was seen as anathema. Even by
the middle of the period, the flaws of simple-mindedness on this question
were obvious. And by the close of the decade, extreme marketism was
possibly even more exposed than the strategies it had defeated, especially
with respect to financial markets.
In India, however, at least in the corridors of power, all this is
yet to become news. The Finance Ministry apparently persists in the
belief that financial markets can function efficiently to increase savings
and allocate them to the most socially desirable investments with minimal
government regulation, and that liberalising the rules for capital entry
and exit in the country is the best way of stabilising and benefiting
from such flows. Such axioms must have underwritten the latest financial
liberalisation measures as outlined in the Budget, and recent official
expositions on the subject have left no doubt of the firmness of these
beliefs.
Elsewhere, of course, that optimistic vision has been greatly tempered,
not only by the sobering experience of many emerging markets over the
decade, but also by theoretical developments in economics which have
highlighted the possibility of many kinds of market failure specific
to financial markets. What is now widely accepted is that some kinds
of regulation may be necessary, not just to prevent or mitigate the
effects of capital flight, but even to control periodic rushes of capital
entry which can have destabilising effects.
This perception has now come home even to the multilateral institutions
that have been seen as the high priests of market-driven economic philosophy.
Thus, the World Bank, in its most recent edition of the annual publication
Global Development Finance, makes arguments which - if made in
India by less hallowed sources - would be immediately dismissed by market
apologists as typical leftist ranting.
To emphasise this point, some of the discussion in this recent World
Bank report deserves fuller quotation at some length : "All past
episodes of surges in capital flows to emerging markets have ended in
severe international financial crises. Hard landings rather than soft
landings have been the rule... Booms in private capital flows to emerging
markets have been punctuated by frequent banking and exchange rate crises
in the capital-receiving countries, and have usually ended in severe
economic dislocation or political conflict. By contrast, financial crises
and debt overhangs were relatively rare during the Bretton Woods era,
when capital controls and stringent financial sector regulation limited
capital flows to emerging markets (although several exchange rate crises
did occur).
" It remains extremely difficult to determine to what extent
these periodic reversals of capital flows have been themselves the cause
of crises or a response to fundamental economic problems in the borrowing
economies. Certainly such reversals have responded to excessive levels
of debt, terms-of-trade shocks, or other events that reduce the prospects
for economic growth in the borrowing countries. However, actions by
creditor countries or lending institutions also have contributed. Crises
have been sparked by monetary tightening in creditor countries and sudden
changes in tolerance for risk on the part of lenders. Creditors have
also contributed to crises by continuing to lend even in the face of
evidence that funds were being directed to activities that could not
generate sufficient returns with which to repay the debts created."
(World Bank, Global Development Finance 2000, Washington, D.
C., page 120).
On a similar note, the World Bank report is cautious about reacting
to the possibility of a renewed spurt in capital flows to developing
countries such as India, the prospect of which currently causes so much
excitement among our own policy makers. Thus, while it recognises that
the current pause in capital flows could last for some years, it also
suggests that factors such as continued technological progress, rapid
economic growth, a favourable political climate, and the ageing of industrial
country populations (compared to the much younger age structure of most
emerging markets) may well lead to a renewed boom in capital flows to
emerging markets over the next decade.
The point, however, is that even such a renewed boom is not seen as
necessarily a cause for celebration among the host emerging economies.
Thus, the report argues that "if these inflows continue to be as
volatile as they have been in the past, their benefits to the developing
world may be reduced. Also, the spread of capital flows to countries
with weak institutional capacity may increase the likelihood of crises
in those economies. The great differences in incomes, legal and institutional
frameworks, and cultural backgrounds between creditors and borrowers
will tend to heighten the effects of asymmetric information and encourage
herding among lenders. The growing role of banking systems in emerging
markets in intermediating volatile capital flows could lead to greater
risk to financial systems and could intensify the devastating effects
of crises on economic output, particularly given the weakness of banking
systems in many countries. Finally, continued financial innovation is
likely to facilitate speculation and the rapid shifting of flows in
and out of emerging markets." (page 120)
To counter these possible adverse consequences
(note, of the boom in inflows as well, not just of the slump),
the World Bank appears to have made a giant leap in its thinking in
terms of recognising the relevance and viability of some capital controls.
(Or could it just be the public swan song of the institution's departing
Chief Economist, Joseph Stiglitz ?) Thus the report seriously considers
a variety of capital control measures, ranging from taxation of short-term
capital inflows to prudential controls on capital inflows, and also
controls on capital outflows during crisis episodes along with liquidity-enhancing
measures such as higher foreign currency reserves and contingent access
to international credit. It allows that both the "market-friendly"
prudential measures regulating inflows in Chile and the mid-crisis measures
to control capital flight in Malaysia could have played important roles.
But what is most important is that the report accepts that such controls
need to be developed within countries according to specific requirements
of particular economies.
Certainly the report recognises that such safeguards would impose
costs on the domestic economy either by restricting the quantity of
foreign borrowing or by raising its price. However, it quite sensibly
points out that such costs are clearly likely to be less than the cost
of a full-fledged financial crisis. What is even more significant is
that finally the Bank also recognises the distributive element in such
policy choices, since financial crises typically make the poor pay for
the subsequent adjustment by bringing about fairly deep recessions which
increase both unemployment and poverty. Regulations on capital flow,
by contrast, tend to put a greater part of the adjustment on to those
who actually benefit more directly from foreign borrowing.
All this is no more than a rather belated recognition (by an institution
that is known for belated and partial responses) of the hard reality
broadcast by the succession of financial crises that have hit emerging
markets over the 1990s. But in the context of the currently ruling economic
ideology in India, it appears not just heretical but impossible in terms
of gaining official acceptance, if only because this echoes belatedly
much of what Indian critics have written about the policies being followed
in our country at the behest of the Bretton Woods institutions.
Obviously, the time will eventually come when these ideas are accepted
generally by Indian policy makers and their economists as well. It remains
to be seen whether this will simply follow the usual intellectual time-lag,
or will be the result of bitter experience.
|