It is presumably the latter
possibility that explains the CACP’s decision to
recommend a substantial hike in MSP’s for oilseeds and
pulses that would encourage a shift in acreage away
from cereals to these kinds of crops. While this may
have a short-term impact on procurement and stock
levels, in the long run diversification ensured
through the procurement price mechanism would lead to
the recurrence of the same problem. With trade in
agricultural commodities liberalised under the WTO,
the high floor price for oilseeds and pulses may lead
to a situation where the market is dominated by
imported varieties that are cheap, rather than
domestic supplies procured at a cost-plus price and
routed to the market through the procurement system
that would be expensive. The consequent fall in
offtake of domestic oilseeds and pulses may force the
government to hold large stocks of these commodities.
The structure of official stocks may change from
cereals to other commodities, but stocks could remain
high keeping subsidies required to finance carrying
costs high as well.
This implies that the problems of existing and likely
future accumulation of food stocks cannot be dealt
with from the side of supply, so long as the
procurement system is seen as a necessary support to
Indian farmers, which it is. Instead, the problems
have to be dealt with from the demand side. This
requires not just the strengthening of the public
distribution system through which subsidised food
should be supplied to all those wanting to access such
food supplies. It also requires a change in mind-set.
Food stocks need to be seen not as a liability created
by the procurement system but an asset, which should
be put to use in food-for-work programmes geared to
enhancing rural and urban infrastructure and
increasing, thereby, productive employment and
activity and reducing poverty. This would have
economy-wide effects as well that would help restore
industrial growth and contribute to an increase in
government revenues. It would also reduce the food
stock “burden” and help curtail subsides paid out in
the form of carrying costs. Holding back on such
programmes on the ground that they would require rupee
resources that would widen the government’s deficit is
completely indefensible.
Failure to emphasise the demand-side solution to the
problem of excess stocks, strengthens the arguments of
those who demand an MSP freeze merely as the first
step towards dismantling the procurement system by
curtailing its role only to that of garnering stocks
adequate to maintain the minimum buffer. This is seen
as a logical corollary of trade liberalisation and the
effort to reduce the fiscal deficit. The needed
reduction in stock levels, needless to say, cannot be
ensured through a minimum support price programme
accompanied by limited procurement, as some have
suggested it should, since that would make the
decisions as to when, where and how much to procure
completely arbitrary and the system subject to misuse
for political patronage. Not surprisingly, many
advocates of food stock, food subsidy and fiscal
deficit reduction have gone the whole way and
suggested that the system created after the agrarian
crisis of the mid-1960s to ensure that farmers are
supported with a cost-plus, ‘remunerative’ floor
should be done away with.
While this would deal, most regressively, with the
‘problem’ of large food stocks, by foreclosing supply
to the government, it does not address the problem of
pre-existing stocks. Releasing a part of these stocks
in the market would depress prices to an extent that
would render the effort to dismantle the MSP-based
system politically indefensible. It is for reason that
the government has been experimenting with the
possibility of handing over pre-existing stocks at
extremely low prices to exporters. This experiment
with disposing off FCI stocks through exports began in
November 2000, and 1.62 million tonnes of wheat were
exported in 2000-01, and 3.18 million tonnes of wheat
and 1.5 million tonnes of wheat have been delivered
for export till February 15 of the financial year
2001-02. In this year’s EXIM policy this drive is to
be strengthened by subsidising transport costs on food
delivered for exports. As part of the ongoing effort
to do away with the MSP-based procurement system,
which is partly necessitated by the drive to reduce
food subsidies provided to domestic consumers, the
government finds it necessary to subsidise consumers
abroad, at least for some time.
Fortunately, this whole misconceived effort is bound
to prove politically infeasible. When farmers in the
US and the EU are being subsidised in large measure
through income support schemes of various kinds, a
government that is subjecting domestic producers to
import competition can hardly work to dismantle the
little support it has provided its own farmers. The
fact that the government could not implement even the
recommendation that the MSP for wheat should be frozen
because it has been increased to higher than warranted
levels in the recent past, shows that in a period when
huge concessions are being provided to domestic and
foreign industrial and financial capital, the demands
of the agricultural community cannot be completely
ignored. Realising this, it would be best for the
government to work to ease the food stock crisis
through feasible, demand-side measures, in particular,
through the launch of a massive food-for-work
programme. But if recent evidence of the government’s
incompetence on matters of economic governance is an
indication, good sense is unlikely to prevail.