|
|
|
|
Boosting
a Rising Profit Rate |
|
Sep
5th 2007, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
Corporate
results for recent quarters in India point to a rapid
growth in profits. Quarter-on-quarter increases in net
profits of more than 20 per cent are the norm in recent
times. Interestingly, despite this sharp improvement
in profitability, the clamour for a reduction in corporate
tax rates has only increased. Thus, KPMG international
has reportedly released a study recently arguing that
India should reduce its corporate tax rate substantially,
because countries competing with it to attract foreign
direct investment such as China and Singapore are likely
to further reduce their already low rates, undermining
India’s competitiveness in the area (Refer “High corporate
tax can affect FDI inflow: KPMG.”, The Economic Times,
25 July 2007).
"With Hong Kong's corporate tax at 17.5 per cent,
Singapore's 20 per cent and Malaysia's 27 per cent,
these countries, which are also in the process of developing
their economies and with their lower corporate tax rates,
can provide stiff competition to India for attracting
FDI," KPMG International’s global corporate tax
rate survey is quoted as saying. Corporate taxes in
India vary from 33.6 per cent for domestic companies
to 42 per cent for foreign firms.
Given the wide difference in rates between India and
these countries, the cut in rates that would be needed
to regain competitiveness can have significant implications
for government revenues and expenditures. Moreover,
it could trigger competing cuts and set off a race to
the bottom that takes the corporate tax rate to exceeding
low levels. If recommendations of this kind are accepted
by developing countries governments would not have the
wherewithal to finance crucial social expenditures or
would have to rely heaving on higher indirect taxes
such as value added taxes, which being more regressive
in nature would only aggravate the inequality that galloping
profit rates imply.
This, however, is not a largely Indian or even a developing
country phenomenon. Supporting rapidly rising profit
rates and shares with tax cuts seems to be a global
tendency in today’s neoliberal order. Profit rates have
indeed been rising globally, as regulations on capital
are being liberalised and labour markets rendered flexible.
Thus, in its edition of February 10, 2005, The Economist
reported: “According to Merrill Lynch, after-tax profits
in America (based on national-accounts data, which is
more reliable than firms' reported data) rose from about
5.5% of national income in the early 1990s to more than
9% in 2003. American profit margins are now close to
a record. The picture is remarkably similar elsewhere.
The share of profits in GDP both in Europe and Japan
is close to a 25-year high. Taken as a whole, the share
of profits in national income for the G7 rich economies
has never been higher, calculates UBS.”
This trend has only continued. A recent study by Luci
Ellis and Kathryn Smith (“The global upward trend in
the profit share”, Bank for International Settlements
Working Paper No. 231) finds that “Profits growth has
been strong in many developed economies in recent years,
and the profit share – the share of factor income going
to capital – has been high compared with historical
experience.” In fact, profit shares have trended upwards
since as far back as the mid 1980s.
Yet, The Economist noted, President George Bush in his
second term had an economic agenda with three goals:
“First, convince Americans that the economy is actually
doing well. Second, credit all good economic news to
the tax cuts. Third, push hard for making the existing
tax cuts permanent.” Bush’s predilections were clear
in his statement that “There's a mindset in Washington
that says, you cut the taxes, we're going to have less
money to spend.” In sum, he wanted to believe that tax
cuts raise revenues rather than reduce them.
In fact, there is a concerted effort even in the financial
media to get governments to use the notion of a “Laffer
curve” to justify arguments for substantially reducing
taxes on profits. The idea of such a curve with particular
characteristics has been used since the mid 1970s to
promote tax cuts for the rich, on the ground that this
would result in an increase in tax revenues for the
government. The curve reflects the view that when tax
rates rise, initially revenues gained from such rates
would rise, but beyond some maximal point any further
increase in taxes would in fact reduce revenues either
because individuals would work less rather than earn
more and have it taxed away or because they would find
ingenious ways of avoiding tax payments. In sum, any
country which is to the right of the maximum would gain
by reducing tax rates either because it would have the
supply side effect of encouraging more work and output
and therefore generating more taxes or would ensure
greater tax compliance and therefore increase tax revenues.
In practice a whole host of factors including a nation’s
per capita income, the extent of income inequality,
perceptions of what the government does with tax revenues,
the nature and efficacy of the tax administration and
the justice implicit in the tax system go to determine
the revenue (relative to GDP) generated by a given structure
of taxes. This implies that what is the optimal maximum
tax rate is impossible to specify, unless a lot of variables
are taken as given and their effects are presumed to
be understood. Yet, sections of the rich who have always
believed that any prevailing tax rate is too high have
pushed this view consistently, even if not through the
medium of a formal curve. Economists inclined to advance
that view have also used the notion in various ways.
The idea of a curve with theoretical and empirical substance
gained currency during the Reaganite years of indiscriminate
tax cuts, with the idea reportedly attributed by Wall
Street Journal correspondent Jude Wanniski to Arthur
Laffer, a subsequent member of Reagan’s Economic Policy
Advisory Board, who is supposed to have drawn the curve
for her education on a napkin. Popularity, of course,
invites attention. And innumerable economists have spent
time and energy to show that the concept is theoretically
hollow and empirically unsubstantiated. This seems to
have influenced even the US Congress with the US Congressional
Budget Office questioning it validity in a 2005 paper.
But given the interest behind promoting the idea and
the support of influential media of the kind that the
Wall Street Journal represents, the idea has just not
gone away. Since the rise of the Laffer curve idea in
the 1970s taxes have been cut many times over across
the world. Yet it is routinely invoked to justify further
cuts in taxes. The point is that even today influential
newspapers like the Wall Street Journal promote the
idea, based on obviously mistaken reasoning.
Consider for example a recent report in the Wall Street
Journal titled “We’re Number One, Alas” (13 July, 2007).
Lamenting that the US is not among the 25 developed
nations that have opted for “Reaganite corporate tax
cuts” since 2001, the newspaper provides two reasons
why the US government should follow the path adopted
by these countries and others such as Vietnam. First,
it makes the country a more attractive site for foreign
investment. This, however, is unlikely to attract a
country which without much effort draws on the world’s
capital to finance its huge trade and current account
deficit. But there is a second reason, according to
the Journal: “Lower corporate tax rates with fewer loopholes
can lead to more, not less, tax revenue from business.
… Tax receipts tend to fall below their optimum potential
when corporate tax rates are so high that they lead
to the creation of loopholes and the incentive to move
income to countries with a lower tax rate.”
Note the subtle shift in argument. Reduce corporate
tax rates to prevent incomes from moving out of the
country in search of relative tax havens. So you have
to reduce tax rates either to attract FDI or to prevent
capital flight of a kind. If every country begins to
do this, the race to the bottom can take corporate tax
rates to near zero. The call is not for international
agreements that prevent such tax evasion, but to reduce
taxes on fat corporate profits in a world where intra-country
inequality is clearly rising. What is shocking is that
this line of reasoning is backed up with the accompanying
graph that ostensibly delivers a smooth Laffer-type
curve from cross-country data. To any student with simple,
school-level graphing skills it should be clear that
using the low tax UAE and a median-tax outlier like
Norway to draw the curve is a basic error, since all
other points do not match its trajectory.
Yet using that graph the Journal approvingly quotes
an “expert”, Kevin Hassett, an economist at the American
Enterprise Institute whose view as expected is that
the U.S. "appears to be a nation on the wrong side
of the Laffer Curve: We could collect more revenues
with a lower corporate tax rate."
Arguments of this kind abound in India as well, with
the Finance Minister often providing support for such
views. It needs to be noted that, despite having a scheduled
corporate tax rate that is higher than in many countries,
the effective tax rate for the private corporate sector
in India continues to be low due to myriad exemptions.
This led to the emergence of highly profitable zero
tax companies, and has necessitated periodic recourse
to a minimum alternate tax. In such a situation, to
invoke the FDI flight bogey to cut corporate tax rates
is merely to find an excuse to use fiscal policy to
engineer a shift in income distribution in favour of
the rich.
Chart
1 >>
Chart 2 >>
|
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|