|
|
|
|
Economic Reform and Inflation |
|
Sep
21st 2004, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
Inflation
is clearly a cause for concern for the UPA government.
Among the few economic policy initiatives it has taken
in its less-than-four months in office, efforts to rein
in inflation dominate. The reason: As on August 28,
the point-to-point annual rate of inflation as measured
by the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) stood at 8.33 per
cent. The climb to that figure has been consistent,
starting from 4.2 per cent on an annualised basis on
May 1.
Chart
1 >>
Interestingly, other than an effort to squeeze liquidity
by raising the cash reserve ratio, the government's
anti-inflation drive has focused on individual commodities
such as oil, steel and sugar. This is because the evidence
indicates that the inflationary spurt is in large part
accounted for by a few commodity groups.
Chart
2 >>
Specifically, the sharp rise in the inflation rate is
attributable to Fuel, Primary articles and Steel, with
Sugar playing a small role as well. At the beginning
of May this year, this set of commodities contributed
a total of 2.7 percentage points to the 4.2 per cent
inflation rate. By August 21, they contributed 5.2 percentage
points to the 8.2 per cent inflation rate.
Chart
3 >>
Thus throughout the period of the inflationary spurt,
these commodities accounted for between 63 and 71 per
cent of the annualised inflation rate computed every
week. In fact, even the residual one-third of the inflation
rate is in part attributable to some of these commodities.
These commodities, especially oil and steel, enter into
the costs of production of a range of others, with oil
being in the nature of a universal intermediate. Hence,
any increase in their prices has second-order effects
that translate into a more generalised inflation. The
sharp increase in oil and steel prices relative to the
corresponding period of the previous year would have
raised the costs of production and therefore the prices
of all commodities, including those that are implicitly
being categorised under the residual ‘Others' category
in this discussion. Thus, any assessment of the factors
underlying inflation has to focus on the factors that
cause the price rise in this set of commodities.
Seen in these terms, the current inflation appears to
be driven substantially by external factors, since domestic
inflation in oil and steel is obviously driven by international
price trends. In the case of oil, a host of developments
varying from the war in Iraq, the troubles in Venezuela
and the controversies that dog the Russian oil industry,
have ensured that prices continue to rule well above
the $40-per-barrel level. Given the much lower levels
at which oil prices prevailed during the corresponding
months of the previous year, the figures yield a high
annualised increase in international oil prices.
Steel prices too have been buoyant for a long time now.
Global steel prices rebounded sharply in 2002 from a
20-year low the year before. Since then they have been
buoyant, sustained by a surge in demand from China.
In 2003, the sharp rise in consumption in Asia and particularly
in China had helped offset stagnation in the West and
brightened the outlook for the leading steel producers
in Europe, Japan and the US, which had otherwise been
cutting production in order to support prices. They
had by then opted to exploit the strong market with
higher margins that spelt high profits.
Since then demand in China has remained strong despite
expectations that it would taper off. According to the
International Iron and Steel Institute (IISI), the world's
steel demand is forecast to swell to 917 million tons
this year, breaking through the 900-million-ton mark
for the first time. Chinese demand for steel products
is predicted to reach 263 million tons in 2004, accounting
for 29 per cent of the total global demand. With China's
high steel consumption expected to last, global steel
demand is projected to grow at an annual average of
4.6 per cent, reaching 1.04 billion tons in 2007. In
the event, international steel prices are expected to
keep their uptrend even after 2005 owing to a supply-demand
imbalance.
These developments in the international economy have
impacted India adversely because the government's liberalisation
policy has either consciously sought to link domestic
prices to world prices or trade liberalisation has ensured
that border prices drive domestic prices in the country.
Prior to the repeal of the administered pricing regime
in oil, its domestic price was considered one of the
instruments of the government tax-cum-subsidy regime.
As domestic prices were stable when international oil
prices fell, the oil companies accumulated surpluses
through an implicit tax on consumers, which were available
for investment purposes or were transferred to the government's
budget. On the other hand, when international oil prices
ruled high, the oil companies incurred losses which
had to be either implicitly (through finance for expenditures)
or explicitly be subsidised by the government through
its revenues from elsewhere. The repeal of administered
pricing has meant that fluctuations in global oil prices
directly impact the consumer.
In the case of steel, matters are slightly different.
Prior to steel price decontrol, domestic prices were
fixed at a level that covered domestic costs of production
and offered producers a reasonable rate of return. But
even after decontrol, any tendency for the prices of
the metal or its products to rise excessively because
of buoyant market conditions was implicitly controlled,
because of the strong presence of the public sector
enterprises in the industry and the strong arm of the
government in the public sector. Liberalisation has
changed all that. Internal liberalisation has meant
that domestic producers, including the public sector,
are free to set prices depending on what the market
would bear. And with restrictions on imports and exports
removed under the liberalised trade policy, what the
market would bear has come to be determined by the level
of global prices. Thus, international supply and demand
balances determine domestic steel prices as well.
It could be argued that given the high share of imported
crude and oil products in domestic consumption, some
link between domestic and international prices is inevitable,
if the government is not to be subsidising oil consumption
indiscriminately. But the same argument can hardly apply
to steel where domestic prices have risen sharply despite
the ability of the domestic industry to meet domestic
demand. According to official sources, the domestic
price of hot-rolled coils had increased to Rs 29,875
per tonne in May 2004 from Rs 20,500 per tonne in January
2003 and Rs 15,500 per tonne in January 2002. Similarly,
the price of cold-rolled coils had risen to Rs 34,300
per tonne in May 2004 from Rs 26,000 per tonne in January
2003 and just Rs 19,500 per tonne in January 2002. Cost
increases do not explain the price spurt, and has resulted
in huge profits for the steel producers.
In sum, India's dependence on imports of crude oil and
her integration into the world steel market, combined
with a more market-driven pricing system, has contributed
in substantial measure to the current rate of inflation.
The net effect is that in the case of both oil and steel,
liberalisation has meant that global trends have resulted
in sharp increases in domestic prices as well. These
price increases have resulted in these contributing
as much as 1.5-1.7 percentage points each to the 6-7.5
per cent rate of inflation between mid-June and early-August.
The price increase has been partly moderated through
a reduction in duties imposed on petroleum and petroleum
products. But so long as the view that domestic oil
prices should keep pace with international values prevails,
there are limits to which the domestic inflation rate
can be insulated from the effects of international oil
price trends.
Unfortunately, this has been combined with an indifferent
and uneven monsoon that was delayed substantially in
many parts of the country. While this is not expected
to result in agricultural output shortfalls of the kind
witnessed in 2002-03, production is not likely to equal
that in 2003-04. Fortunately, given the current food
stock position, this would not result in any imbalance
between demand and supply. However, the uncertainties
over the monsoon have provided the basis for speculative
price increases in the case of a number of primary commodities,
resulting in a significant inflation in the wholesale
price indices for Primary articles. As a result this
too has contributed to the sharp rise in prices.
Finally, in the case of sugar, a decline in production
over two years has resulted in a significant fall in
the level of stockholding. This has triggered a price
increase, fuelled by speculation, even though international
prices in this case have been subdued.
The congruence of this set of factors explains the return
of inflation, which once again is grabbing headlines.
It must be said that, compared to its lethargy in most
other areas, the government's response on this front
has been quick and varied. This response has included
duty cuts on petro-products and steel, a 50-basis-point
hike in the cash reserve ratio and relaxation of the
norms with regard to sugar imports. Raw sugar imports
are now allowed duty-free with the obligation to export
from domestic production within 24 months. In the case
of steel, the government has also sought to deal with
this problem by forcing domestic producers to hold and
even cut their prices.
Thus the response is three-fold in nature. First, it
attempts to moderate the effects of global price movements
on domestic inflation by making compensatory reductions
in domestic duties and persuading domestic suppliers
to hold their prices. Secondly, it attempts to dampen
speculation by reducing liquidity in the system through
measures such as the hike in the cash reserve ratio.
And, thirdly, it seeks to reverse domestic price increases
by facilitating larger imports.
None of these is likely to be effective enough to deal
with the problem. However, the problem is that in the
wake of liberalisation, the government has left itself
with few options to deal with situations like this.
Duty cuts can only be carried to a limit, and in any
case worsen the government's already weak fiscal position.
The use of monetary levers is ineffective and already
under attack from industry because it could push up
interest rates. And imports are not an effective option
since it is international prices that drive domestic
inflation in any case. So long as increases in the international
prices of oil and steel persist and the link between
domestic and international prices is not sought to be
directly broken, measures such as duty reductions can
only serve as short-term and partial palliatives. It
is also unlikely that half-hearted measures to reduce
liquidity can make any difference to speculation. And,
finally, easier imports can make a difference only in
the case of commodities like sugar and edible oils,
in whose case international prices are subdued. But
their contribution to the inflation rate is the least.
Hence, unless there is a change in policy stance, inflation
is likely to persist so long as international prices
of oil and steel remain buoyant and the base for speculative
price increases in primary commodities exists.
The danger is that this inflation driven by international
price trends and speculation rather than by demand-supply
imbalances would provide an argument for further fiscal
contraction, even though food stocks, foreign exchange
reserves and unutilised capacity warrant an expansionary
fiscal stance. If that happens, the still slow progress
on implementing the National Common Minimum Programme
would soon be halted.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|