A caveat is called for at this point. It is well known and widely accepted
that the reliability of the IIP declines when we move to more
disaggregated levels of industry. Further, there is a substantial degree
of overlap between the capital and consumer non-durable categories.
Automobiles, purchases of which for personal use rose substantially during
the 1990s, are included in the capital goods category. So are electronic
goods of certain kinds that would be more appropriately classified as
consumer-durables. This overflow of consumer durables into the capital
goods category makes it difficult to assess the degree to which any slump
or recovery in capital goods is driven by consumer durables. It also
implies that the small weight of consumer durables in the overall index,
does not do full justice to the importance of this sector from the point
of view of industrial growth.
All this is of relevance when we seek to explain the process of growth and
industrial deceleration during the 1990s. It needs to be recognised that
the liberalisation programme of the 1990s had a number of adverse
implications for manufacturing and industrial growth. To start with, it
was inevitable that import liberalisation would result in some
displacement of existing domestic production either directly by imports or
indirectly by new products assembled domestically from imported inputs.
Second, that the reduction in customs duties resorted to as part of the
import liberalisation package and the direct and indirect tax concessions
that were provided to the private sector to stimulate investment,
especially starting with the budget of 1993-94, would lead to a
significant reduction in the tax-GDP ratio at the Centre by anywhere
between 1.5 to 2 percentage points of GDP. This implied that the fiscal
stimulus associated with any given level of the fiscal deficit would be
lower than would have otherwise been the case. Finally, after some initial
slippage in the deficit reduction effort, which took the fiscal deficit to
relatively high levels in 1993-94, the government has managed closer even
if not full adherence to fiscal deficit targets, so that the stimulus
provided to industrial growth by state expenditure was substantially
smaller than was the case in the 1980s.
Chart 11 >>
Chart 12 >>
Chart 13 >>
It is despite all this that India witnessed the three-year mini-boom in
industrial growth during 1993-94 to 1995-96, which as we have seen has had
an overwhelming influence on the trend rate of industrial growth during
the 1990s. The explanation for this boom, despite the adverse consequences
of liberalisation for growth in industry, lies in the effects of
liberalisation on demand. It has been known for some time that one
consequence of the complex of import substitution policies pursued by
India till the mid 1980s was the pent-up demand for a range of
manufactured goods, including specific brands of such goods. While
knowledge of these could be acquired by consumers and producers from the
international market, the products themselves could either not be acquired
within India or acquired only at prohibitive costs. Liberalization of the
kind pursued in India, which freed access to intermediates, components and
capital goods while protecting most end-products, along with reducing
tariffs substantially, allowed for the expansion of domestic
production/assembly and sale of these commodities in a relatively short
span of time. This occurred at two levels : first, by relatively small
firms that combined cheap imports and domestic parts to service what is
not always correctly described as the "grey market"; and second, by larger
firms, very often in collaboration with international producers with a
well-cultivated brand image.
While such products did have a ready market, they would not have
contributed to a net addition to domestic production to the extent that
they displaced similar or other products in the consumer's basket of
purchases. If the availability of new goods were to spur growth it needed
to be accompanied by a net accretion to demand after accounting for the
displacement of previously available "substitutes". In the short run such
net additions to demand can be financed either with the flow of hitherto
unaccounted incomes into the market for goods, or with an element of
dissaving reflected by reduced financial savings, or through increased
recourse to consumer credit. There is reason to believe that in much of
urban India and some parts of rural India, such a tendency was underway,
driven by easier access to credit, including consumer credit provided to
individuals.
Chart 14 >>
Chart 15 >>
Chart 16 >>
The 1993-1995 "mini-boom" was thus the result of a combination of several
once-for-all influences, in particular the release of the pent-up demand
for a host of import-intensive goods, which (because of liberalization)
could be serviced through domestic assembly or production using imported
inputs and components. Once that demand had been satisfied, further growth
had to be based on an expansion of the domestic market or a surge in
exports. Since neither of these conditions was realised, industry then
entered a phase of slow growth, though the percolation of such demand to
lower income deciles facilitated by the consumer credit boom, kept
consumption goods growth going at above average levels in many years. That
is, the phenomenon of ‘pent-up' demand was not restricted to those who had
the wherewithal to realize it as soon as supply-side constraints to their
realization were removed. The tendency existed among other sections as
well, and could realise itself in the form of actual demand because
financial liberalisation, which had as its corollary the entry of new
financial players into the market and the diversification of banks and
non-bank financial companies into new areas of lending that promised
higher returns, resulted in a boom in consumer credit that substantially
increased the number of people who could lumpy purchases. Further, the
‘windfall gains' registered by a significant number of central and state
government employees as a result of the payment of arrears following of
the implementation of the Fifth Pay Commission's recommendations, also
contributed to n increase in the number having the wherewithal to
contribute to such demand. It is indeed true that while industrial firms
and rich agriculturalists contributed to such pent-up demand as well, the
bulk of such purchases would be of consumer durables by households. This
explains the more consistent performance of the consumer durables sector.
It follows that when such demand is satiated and cannot be sustained any
further, the overall tendency is towards slower industrial growth on
average if other stimuli such as state expenditure do not substitute for
the once-for-all stimulus, as was true by the end of the decade.