At the
centre of the process of integration advanced by liberalisation and
globalisation during the 1990s stands the multinational corporation. And
in terms of visibility and importance, US multinationals like General
Motors, IBM, Microsoft and Coca Cola, occupy a pre-eminent position.
This makes the release by the United States government’s Bureau of
Economic Affairs (BEA) of the preliminary results of the 1999 benchmark
survey of US direct investment abroad an event of some significance. A
US MNC in the BEA data comprises a US parent company and its affiliates
abroad. Much of the BEA data relate to majority owned foreign affiliates
(MOFAs), which accounted for 84 per cent of employment of all non-bank
foreign affiliates. For some time now the BEA has been conducting
benchmark surveys or censuses of these MNCs once in five years, and
annual sample surveys for the intervening years. Comparable benchmark
surveys are available for the years 1982, 1989, 1994 and 1999,
permitting a preliminary assessment of the changing role and impact of
multinational operations during the years of globalisation.
The
BEA’s data do point to an acceleration of the expansion of US
multinationals (Charts 1 and 2). Over the 17-year period 1982-99, the
nominal gross product of and employment in US multinationals grew at an
annual rate of 5.1 and 1.2 per cent respectively. This average trend
conceals, however, a moderate acceleration in the rate of growth of
gross product and employment from 4.3 and 0.1 per cent respectively
during 1982 to 1989, to 5.7 and 1.9 per cent during 1989-99. Further, if
we break down the 1989-99 period, the evidence seems to point to a
substantial increase in rates of growth of gross product and employment
from 4.7 and 0.3 per during 1989-94 to 6.6 and 3.5 per cent. These
trends, Charts 1 and 2 indicate, separately hold for parents of US
multinationals and their majority owned foreign affiliates (MOFAs) as
well. It is no doubt true that trends in nominal gross product figures
may be vitiated by price movements. However, the facts that inflation
has been subdued the world over during the 1990s and that employment
figures follow gross product movements, make these trends representative
of actual events.
Chart 1 >>
Chart
2 >>
There
are two sets of issues which the acceleration in the growth of US MNCs
raise. First, are issues related to the impact of that acceleration on
the structure of output and employment in the US economy. The second,
are issues relating to the impact of these multinationals globally, and
in particular on developing countries. The more conservative
apprehensions regarding globalisation are based on the possibility that
the growing importance of multinational corporations could reflect a
process of hollowing out of economic activity in the developing
countries and their relocation abroad, resulting in job and production
losses in the metropolitan centres of global capitalism. Those who argue
that liberalisation and globalisation are positive from the point of
view of the developing countries also advance a less asymmetric version
of this argument. In that view, globalisation, besides increasing the
incomes of developed country corporations with attendant positive
consequences in those countries, allows for an expansion of production,
employment and exports in developing countries, driven by multinational
corporations.
In these views, the
defining feature of foreign direct investment (FDI) during the years of
globalisation is that each enterprise-level investment decision is a
component of a larger process of relocation of whole industries from
sites in more industrially developed economies to less developed ones,
resulting in the global restructuring of industrial production.
Relocation takes its "ideal" form, which involves the once-for-all or
gradual closure by more developed country producers of capacity at home
and the establishment by the same producers of equal or larger
capacities in developing country sites. This trend towards relocation,
if it occurs, reflects a change in the nature of global flows of FDI
during the years of liberalization and globalisation.
With the wave of liberalisation that began in the early 1980s, it is
argued, the relevance of foreign investment stimulated by
import-substituting policies in the developing world has declined. The
removal of non-tariff barriers to trade and the reduction of tariffs on
most imports, have done away with the need to jump barriers to control
markets. Most developing country markets can be accessed as easily
through imports from abroad of commodities either in their final form or
ready for assembly. The corollary is that foreign investments aimed at
catering to domestic markets must be competitive with imports accessible
at relatively low tariff rates. That is, the segmentation of the world
market that the import-substituting years implied and the consequent
distinction between sites for local market-oriented production and world
market-oriented production is disappearing. Investments aimed at
catering to domestic markets should be capable, therefore, of catering
to the world market. The resulting dissociation between sites of
production and markets implies that a firm would now choose to invest in
a particular location only if that site can serve as one of the
production locations for its world market operations. Thus, when an
enterprise chooses a new location for investment it is in essence
"relocating" capacity that can service the local market, or its
erstwhile "home"-country market, or its third country markets or some
combination of those markets.