To quote the OECD study referred to earlier: "Copies of movies and most
other performances can be recorded and mass-produced for future
consumption, like manufactured products. Software is developed and boxed
like any other manufactured product, and is considered, for all intents
and purposes, a good - albeit with a high service-related content. In
these instances services have, in a sense, taken on the characteristics of
commodities - one provider is mass-producing a common product for many
people." (OECD 2000)
Technology, in particular the revolution in information and communication
technologies (ICT), is seen to play a crucial role here, providing a
material link between the new economy argument and the evidence on the
growth of services. The ICT revolution, it is argued, helps transform a
service produced for a single or few consumers, to one that is produced
for mass consumption. This allows the service 'industry' to exploit
economies of scale just as manufacturing has been doing ever since the
industrial revolution. A service, such as an online database for example,
produced and placed on the internet, can be accessed by a large number of
consumers. The revolution in ICT also changes the relationship between
providers and consumers, with the latter being able to access services
like health, banking and financial services and entertainment without
personal onsite contact with the provider. Easier access, which implies
easier delivery, also allows for growing differentiation and rapid
diversification of the services 'products' offered to consumer, as has
indeed been true.
The blurring of the distinction between goods and services is seen to be
true in the financial services area as well. To quote the OECD study
referred to above: "There was a time when a bank would lend to a business
or provide a mortgage, would take the asset and put it on their books much
the way a museum would place a piece of art on the wall or under glass -
to be admired and valued for its security and constant return. Times have
changed. Banks now take those assets, structure them into pools, and sell
securities based on those pools to institutional investors and portfolio
managers. In effect, they use their balance sheets not as museums, but as
parking lots - temporary holding spaces to bundle up assets and sell them
to those investors who have a far greater interest in holding those assets
for the long term. The bank has thus gone from being a museum where it
acquired only the finest assets and held and exhibited them in perpetuity
into a manufacturing plant which provides a product for the secondary
market. Just as Henry Ford did 80 years ago, banks today are focusing on
producing a standardised product at a predictable rate, under standard
norms of quality, and are teaching their workforces to produce that
product as quickly and as efficiently as possible." The implicit premise
here is that the fact that there is no production process, does not make a
difference to the productive nature of the operation. The principal
argument is that the 'industry of origin' of GDP matters less today. If
commodity production recedes and service activities burgeon, that is just
one more reflection of the new capitalism.
Is this argument supported by the changing structure of the services
sector itself? Table 5 presents the shares of the principal service sector
activities in the gross product of the service sector as a whole in the
US. What emerges is that conventional service sector activities like
Transportation, Communication and Public Utilities, the Wholesale Trade
and Retail Trade have shrunk in relative terms, with their relative
decline being particularly sharp after 1970. The two sectors that have
gained have been Financial and Real Estate Services and 'Other Services',
with the increase in share being particularly marked in the latter.
Table 5 >>
Tables 6 and 7 provide a picture of trends in the share of different
services in total full-time equivalent employment and self-employment
respectively in the US. Here again the picture is quite clear, though
slightly in variance with the trends in distribution of gross product.
Conventional services have tended to decline in relative terms. In the
case of full-time equivalent employment, the gainers are the Retail Trade
(which includes the all important automobile services), Finance and other
general services. In the case of Self-employment only the financial and
general services sectors are gainers. The last of these has recorded a
remarkable 14.6 percentage points in relative share in full-time
equivalent employment and 10.7 percentage points in relative share in
self-employment.
Table 8 disaggregates the distribution of full-time equivalent employment
in the general "Services" category covered by the data. The results are
striking indeed. Services employment in the private household sector has
collapsed. Health and Social Services that expanded during the first two
to three decades after 1950, has since been on the decline in terms of
their relative share in employment. So has the personal services sector.
The two major gainers that in relative share in employment have been
Business Services and Miscellaneous Services. Thus the evidence points to
a growing corporatisation of service sector employment, with a market
shift in favour of business services of the kind discussed above.
Table 6 >>
However, the evidence suggests that this second-tier diversification
within services in favour of business services is not as "productive" as
it is often made out to be. The little evidence that exists points to a
slowdown in productivity growth in services after 1973. To quote a recent
study by economists at the Brookings Institution (Triplett and Bosworth
1999): "From 1949 to 1973, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) estimates
that U.S. non-farm multifactor productivity grew at 1.9% per year. After
1973, multifactor productivity grew only 0.2% per year. Despite a 20-year
intensive research effort to find the cause, no convincing explanation of
the post-1973 productivity slowdown exists.
Whatever the ultimate cause, circumstantial evidence suggests that
services industries play some important role in the slowdown. In the first
place, the aggregate numbers indicate that the productivity slowdown is
greater in the non-goods producing portions of the economy. While no
official estimate of productivity in services is published by the Bureau
of Labour Statistics, nonfarm multifactor productivity slowed by 1.7
percentage points (from 1.9% per year to 0.2%), and manufacturing
productivity fell by 0.6 percentage points (from 1.5% per year to 0.9%).
Because manufacturing accounts for about 22% of non-farm business, this
implies a two-percentage point slowdown in the non-manufacturing sector.
Thus, the evolution of the services sector in the developed industrial
countries points in a number of directions. First, the share of services
in gross product and employment in the developed countries has and is
increasing quite substantially. Second, this dependence on services has
been accompanied by signs of growing reliance on a few types of services,
in particular business services, to sustain the boom, while a whole range
of other services including communication, health and educational services
are tending to lag. Third, there are clear signs of the "corporatisation"
of service activity, making its performance crucial from the point of view
of business profitability. Finally, the evidence suggests that this
dependence on services has not been accompanied by increases in the
productivity of services, as new economy theorists have tended to argue.
The lack of evidence of productivity growth implies that firms would be
dependent on extensive rather than intensive growth in the services areas.
Extensive growth is important for two other reasons. Many areas of
services, where "intangibles" are a crucial component of added value, are
characterised by substantial sunk cots in development of the service, but
relatively low costs in the reproduction of the service. Software, whether
business or entertainment software, is an obvious example. Once developed,
such software can be reproduced on any scale at extremely low cost. Thi
makes the volume of profits directly dependent on the size of the market.
Further, many areas of services such as communications, finance and
software development are characterised by substantial "network
externalities". The larger the network, or the number of users, the
greater is the possibility of expansion, since joining the network
provides substantially more benefits to marginal users. Expansion then
becomes a prerequisite for faster growth.
These features of segments of the business services sector generate a
drive for expansion. Since they are accompanied by pressure to find new
markets for lagging services like communication and utilities, a wide
range of service providers are in search of emerging markets. This
encourages them into foreign markets that are serviced either by
exploiting the benefits of digital technology or by establishing a
commercial presence through mergers and acquisitions or greenfield
investments in new markets. According to UNCTAD over 60 per cent of global
mergers and acquisitions (M&A) and as much as 90 per cent in the
developing countries were in the services sector.
Services also account for a significant share of the international trade
of the United States. In 2000, U.S. exports of private services exceeded
U.S. import of private services; U.S. exports were $278.6 billion, while
U.S. imports were $200.6 billion. U.S. exports also exceeded U.S. imports
in 1999; exports were $256.0 billion and imports were $173.0 billion. For
services sold through majority-owned foreign and U.S. affiliates of
multinational companies, U.S. sales exceeded U.S. purchases in 1999 - the
most recent year for which data are available. Sales of services abroad
through foreign affiliates of U.S. companies were $338.4 billion, while
sales of services in the United States through U.S. affiliates of foreign
companies were $289.3 billion. The U.S. surplus on trade in private
services stood at $78.0 billion in 2000 when the U.S. deficit on trade in
goods amounted to $452.2 billion.
This growing importance of services in production, employment, trade and
business profit in the US must influence its position on trade in
services. This is why besides cross-border supply (such as in postal
services), consumption abroad (tourism) and presence of natural persons
(nursing), the GATS agreement covers services provided "by a service
supplier of one member, through commercial presence in the territory of
another member." The OECD seeks to ensure that GATS facilitates and
encourages such investment, that is increasingly crucial for whatever
dynamism the developed industrial countries display.