Third, even the level of the interest rate paid on
open market borrowing has been unduly high because of the regime of
high interest rates that had been ushered in by reform. As the Finance
Minister himself has stressed, real interest rates in India are extremely
high by international standards. What he failed to mention was this
was largely a 1990s phenomenon resulting from a monetary policy that
kept interest rates high partly in order to attract foreign capital
inflows in the wake of financial liberalization. If this had not been
the case, the interest burden on the budget would have been even lower.
Finally, subsidies on food which were budgeted at
Rs. 8210 crore in the budget for 2000-2001, have turned out to be close
to 50 per cent higher at Rs. 12125 crore not because of the largesse
of the government vis-à-vis the poor. Rather it is the result of the
foolishness of the government in raising issue prices repeatedly to
levels even higher than warranted by the increase in procurement prices,
in order to reduce food subsidies. The net result has been a sharp fall
in offtake from the public distribution system. As result, even in a
year when foodgrain output growth has been low, the government has found
itself saddled with huge and rising stocks, which increased its outlays
on the costs of carrying these stocks. A wrong policy aimed at reducing
subsidies has ended up bloating subsidies even further. But even here,
it must be noted, despite this the total subsidies relative to GDP have
not changed substantially in 2000-01, as Chart 4 illustrates.
Chart 4 >>
In sum, the argument attributing the fiscal deficit
to a tendency for expenditures to automatically' overshoot
beyond that warranted by a given level of receipts does not wash. What
has been responsible for the size of the deficit last year is a set
of wrong policies and more crucially a fiscal strategy over time involving
policies such as direct tax concessions and customs duty reductions,
along with financial policies that have substantially raised the interest
outlay in the government's budget.
The reason the Finance Minister seeks to ignore these
aspects of the problem is not hard to find. Driven by the ideology of
neoliberal reform, he wants to continue with the practice of handing
out direct tax concessions, in the hope that this would spur growth.
In this budget these concessions have not merely come in the form of
the withdrawal of surcharges on income taxes, of 10 per cent in the
case of corporates and 15 per cent in the case of non-corporates, without
substituting them with other direct tax levies, but through several
other measures. These include : a reduction on dividends distributed
by domestic companies from 20 to 10 per cent; the exemption from taxation
of capital gains from sale of securities and units so long as they are
reinvested in primary issues of public companies; and the provision
of a host of tax holidays to investments in a range of sectors varying
from infrastructural areas, to ISPs and broadband networks and those
involved in the integrated business of handling, storage and transportation
of foodgrains. These, combined with other concessions, are expected
to result in a revenue loss of Rs. 5,500 crore of direct taxes in a
year. In addition, the drive to reduce customs tariffs even when they
are below those specified in WTO commitments, is expected to result
in a revenue loss of Rs. 2,128 crore.
These losses do not, however, bother Mr. Sinha. He
has partly made up for them through an ostensible restructuring
of excise duties aimed at moving to a single 16 per cent rate of CENVAT
on all commodities. It hardly bears stating that a common rate of duty
on commodities, varying from manufactured necessities like soap to luxuries
like automobiles, is regressive by definition. Yet the Finance Minister's
excise homogenization initiative has involved reducing duties on a range
of luxuries varying from automobiles to refrigerators and increasing
them to double their current ad valorem levels on many mass consumption
goods. The net estimated effect is additional revenue mobilization to
the tune of Rs. 4,467 crore from indirect taxes other customs duties.
However, the shift to a more regressive and inflationary
taxation structure does not help cover the loss of revenue from direct
taxes and customs duties. There are a number of ways in which the Finance
Minister makes up for this debilitating fiscal strategy, in order to
reduce the fiscal deficit to 4.7 per cent of GDP while maintaining a
stable expenditure to GDP ratio. First, he plans to squeeze capital
expenditures. As Chart 5 shows, the ratio of non-defence capital expenditures
to GDP has fallen sharply in the last two years and is budgeted to remain
at that level in the coming year. Second, he believes that tax buoyancy
and voluntary compliance will increase tax revenues by more than 14
per cent next year. Third, he provides for a record Rs. 12,000 to be
garnered from disinvestments of equity in public sector corporations.
Fourth, he has chosen to reduce interest rates on small savings schemes
by a large 1.5 percentage points so as to reduce the interest paid by
the government on such savings. Finally, he has decided to revamp the
pension scheme so as to reduce the outgo on pensions in future. It takes
little to judge who gains and who loses from these initiatives.
Chart 5 >>
|