This gap points in a number of directions. First, the government would
have been more successful in curbing the fiscal deficit if it had not done
away with the practice of monetisation of part of the overall deficit.
Second, if deficits had been maintained at actual levels along with
monetisation, the expansionary effect of recent budgets would have been
quite significant, with positive results on the growth and poverty
alleviation front. And, finally, if the government had not merely stuck
with monetisation but also dropped its obsession with the fiscal deficit,
especially in recent times when food and foreign reserves have been
aplenty, the 1990s would have in all probability been a decade of
developmental advance.
Budget 2000 reflects the fact that the BJP-led government has consciously
chosen to forego this opportunity by making "second generation" reforms
its principal thrust. Central to that strategy is a further push to
financial liberalisation. In hypocritical fashion, the Budget speaks of
formalising the autonomy of the RBI, even while it ties the central bank's
hands by liberalising the conditions for foreign capital inflows.
Financial flows on the capital account into the country have been further
liberalised by offering tax concessions to venture capital funds, raising
the ceiling on equity holding by FIIs investing in firms in secondary
markets to 40 per cent and promising to sell public equity in banks up to
67 per cent of the total, some of which would be picked up by foreign
investors. So long as India remains the flavour of the time with foreign
investors this would only enhance the quantum of foreign capital inflows.
To partly neutralise the impact this would have on the central bank's
operations, the government has chosen to ease the access to foreign
exchange of domestic capitalists for undertaking investments abroad. The
other route through which foreign exchange reserves would be run down is
through the indiscriminate import that is likely to result from
accelerated import liberalisation. Even while the BJP's capitulation to US
pressure to advance the dates for doing away with quantitative
restrictions on the import of 1429 items (714 to April 1, 2000 and another
715 to April 1, 2001) threatens to deindustrialise India and adversely
affect the livelihood of primary producers, the maximum rate of duty on
agricultural products has been reduced from 40 to 35 per cent. Allowing
indiscriminate access to foreign exchange without imposing any conditions
which tie such use to the earning of foreign exchange to meet future
commitments is a sure way of paving the way for financial crises of the
Sutheast Asian kind.
The attack on domestic producers via the import-competition route occurs
in a context where developmental expenditures are being squeezed. While
the Budget claims to increase Plan outlays by 13 per cent relative to last
year's Budget estimates and 22 per cent over the actual spending in
1999-2000, plan outlays in many crucial sectors, such as agriculture,
rural development, irrigation and so on, have actually been lowered. In
addition, the actual spending on these important areas may turn out to be
even lower. Thus, in both the previous fiscal years, the Central
Government spent much less than it had budgeted for in almost all the
crucial sectors of Plan outlay, such as agriculture, rural development,
irrigation, energy, industry and minerals and so on, thus depriving the
economy of important sources of growth. There have also been shortfalls in
expenditure on social services. So these critical areas of spending
continue to be shortchanged.
The slated 13 per cent increase in capital expenditure in this Budget at
first appears to reverse this tendency. However, 80 per cent of the
increase in total capital expenditure is accounted for by defence alone (Chartt
6). One consequence of this 'new militarism' characterising the BJP's
tenure is that, in an effort to dampen US criticism of this tendency, the
government is willing to make huge concessions on the economic front, with
regard to trade and foreign capital flows. The other is that, non-defence
capital expenditure is budgeted to remain stagnant or decline in real
terms.
Chart 6 >>
Further, in his effort to prove that despite this hike in defence outlays,
overall expenditures and the fiscal deficit are to be controlled, the
Finance Minister has chosen to attack food and fertiliser subsidies,
besides capital expenditures unrelated to defence. The orchestrated outcry
on the unsustainable level of food and fertiliser subsidies appears as
almost a conspiracy. In fact, even if we only consider revenue
expenditures other than interest payments (Chart 7), the share of food
subsidies in expenditures has been more or less constant in recent years,
and the combine share of food and fertiliser subsidies has in fact been
falling.
Chart 7 >>
Yet, the most striking "achievement" of this year's budget is that at a
time when the evidence points to a decade-long stagnation or even increase
in the incidence of rural poverty, the prices of food distributed through
the public distribution system are to be hiked to realise a 12 per cent
reduction in food subsidies.
To sanitise this effort, Sinha has presented the subsidy reduction as an
effort to target subsidies at the needy, namely the population below the
poverty line. That population he argues would now be eligible for double
the quota available earlier. What he left virtually unstated was the fact
that this larger quota is available at a per unit price which would be
much higher. Households below the poverty line would now have to bear with
68 per cent increases in the issue prices of wheat and rice.
Even people above the poverty line, many of whom are also poor in a wider
definition, would have to pay 23 per cent more for wheat and 30 per cent
more for rice because they will now be charged the full economic cost. Not
only does this mean that most people who use the PDS system will end up
paying much more, but it also penalises the state governments that have
been running a more broad-based and efficient PDS system. This is because
this price relates to the rate at which the Central Government releases
foodgrain to the individual state governments, some of whom have been
supplying it at a lower rate to consumers through the PDS.
The irony is that, while this measure will clearly hit ordinary people
very hard, it may not lead to a decline in the food subsidy bill at all.
This is because as prices rise, offtake from Fair Price Shops tends to
decline, and so the FCI is left holding even more stocks, with high
carrying costs which add to its losses. This is indeed one reason why the
level of stock holding of foodgrain is already so high.
As mentioned earlier, the availability of large foodstocks with the
government is calls for an effort to use the surplus foodstocks to part
"finance" employment programmes that help strengthen rural infrastructure.
This would have helped improve agricultural growth performance as well as
increase rural incomes and reduce poverty. The Finance Minister has,
however, chosen to ignore this opportunity and pursist with a strategy of
reform that goes to the contrary. The financial component of such reform
requires curbing borrowing from the RBI and cutting a range of
expenditures as part of the effort to appease finance, even if the
consequence is a combination of policies which squeeze the poor and
undermine growth prospects. These are further indicators of the fact that
under the BJP the overall interests of international finance have come to
dominate economic policy making in India. And it is that dominance which
has put the government in a state of paralysis with respect to triggering
growth and reducing poverty. The interests the BJP government seeks to
serve and those it wishes to penalise are therefore clear. |