The net impact
of these developments on foreign exchange flows associated with the
working of these enterprises is discernible from Chart 8. Net foreign
exchange flows, which amounted to an inflow of Rs. 142 crore in 1990-91
and Rs. 529 crore in 1993-94, turned into an outflow of Rs. 186 crore
in 1993-94. That outflow had risen to Rs. 340 crore by 1996-97. What
is more, even in 1990-91, firms in sectors like Engineering and Chemicals,
which were the ones receiving further investments in the subsequent
years of liberalisation of FDI regulations, were already registering
large outflows. It was only because of the inflows into firms in traditional
sectors like Tea, Textiles and Leather, that the aggregate figure
turned out to be positive. The evidence is clear that FDI of the kind
that India has been receiving in the wake of liberalisation is a factor
contributing to a foreign exchange drain rather to an enhancement
of India's foreign exchange earning capacity.
Chart 8 >>
It would, of
course, be argued by the advocates of reform that the drain of foreign
exchange on account of the operations of these firms is more than
matched by the additional inflow in the form of equity capital. This
argument, however, confuses the immediate inflow on account of foreign
investment and the long term sustainability of inflows of the kind
discussed. It is well known that foreign capital inflows into joint
ventures in developing countries are in the nature of large one time
flows for establishing or substantially expanding an enterprise accompanied
by smaller 'in effect' inflows on account of retention of
part of the profits due to the foreign partner, which are not paid
out as dividends.
Once established
much of the expansion of the firm occurs on the basis of borrowing
from the domestic market, or issues of additional shares at a premium.
Such issues are resorted to in the wake of the capitalisation of reserves
through the issue of bonus shares to existing shareholders so that
their stake in the company is not substantially diluted. In the case
of the FDICs in the RBI sample for example, the share of funds used
that were diverted to gross fixed assets formation rose from 33.9
per cent in 1991-92 to 42.2 per cent in 1993-94 and 73.5 per cent
in 1996-97. During these years, the share of external sources of funds,
consisting dominantly of borrowing from the domestic market, accounted
for between 60 and 70 per cent of the total throughout the period
(Chart 9). Expansion results in an increase in the fixed assets, sales
and profits of the company concerned, which in turn increases outflows
on account of imports and non-import foreign exchange expenditures
like royalties that are tied to sales volumes.
Chart 9 >>
Thus, unless
exports increase significantly and bring in additional foreign exchange
revenues, net inflows that are positive at the time when equity is
flowing in soon turn negative, and within a short period cumulative
inflows are negative. It is for this reason that the cumulative foreign
exchange impact of foreign investments targeted at domestic markets
inevitably tends to be negative. There is no reason to believe that
given the nature of FDI flows into India during liberalisation the
story would be any different.
This conclusion
has a larger implication. The theology of liberalisation is based
on the presumption that one of the features of globalisation is the
emergence of large volumes of footloose capital in search of appropriate
locations for world market production. Since every developing country
would have some comparative advantage, it is argued, the liberalisation
of trade and foreign investment rules would attract some of this capital,
which would relocate the relevant capacities to the developing country
concerned, to use it as a source for production for the world market.
Investment flows would be accompanied by trade flows, including exports,
making FDI either benign or virtuous from a balance of payments point
of view. This argument regarding capital mobility is not theoretically
obvious, since a range of factors can distort this picture of freely
flowing capital that redresses production inequalities across the
world. If it is to be valid, it must be empirically shown to be true.
The available evidence relating to FDI during the liberalisation years
suggests that it is not.
|