|
|
|
|
Approaching
the Eleventh Plan |
|
Jul
11th 2006, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
The
most remarkable thing about the Planning Commission's
Approach to the Eleventh Plan is that there appears
to be no planning in it. Planning in the economic sense
requires, at the minimum, a constrained maximisation
exercise - that is, a clear definition of the social
goals, which are then sought to be attained as far as
possible subject to the prevailing resource, economic,
social and technological constraints. This in turn requires
a specification of the proposed mechanisms or measures
to be employed to attain these goals.
This
was certainly present in the earlier Plans of the Government
of India. Even in the 1980s, the Plan documents at least
had the semblance of such minimum discipline, though
it could be argued that by then the governments in power
had less inclination to even try and follow them in
practice. But the current Approach Paper does not even
attempt to provide a clear statement of goals and mechanisms.
Instead, it adopts an uncritical ''trickle-down'' approach
to economic growth, by making the basic objective the
achievement of a certain target annual GDP growth figure
- either 7,8 or 9 per cent per annum - and effectively
assuming that all social goals will be achieved by this.
This is almost criminal since the Approach has tucked
away in it the first official acknowledgement that the
country has been told a fairy tale about poverty reduction
during the 1990s. Till now the growth-first argument
has made much of the contested official claim that poverty
declined from 36 per cent in 1993-94 to 26 per cent
in 1999-2000 or by 10 per cent over a 6 year period.
It is now revealed that the comparable figure for 2004-05
is 28 per cent, which implies only 8 per cent reduction
over a 11 year period. This implies that despite all
the hype on growth, it is now official that the rate
of poverty reduction after 1990 has been at only half
the rate between 1977 to 1990.
In addition to this glaring confusion on whether growth
itself is the objective, or a means to achieving something
more meaningful, the Approach has reduced its ''planning''
exercise to a relatively crude calculation of the projected
growth scenarios and the associated requirements of
public and private savings and investment as well as
sectoral growth rates. These numbers are derived not
just through extrapolating from the past but by making
(often heroic) assumptions regarding what are perceived
to be desired changes, without any consideration of
how these different numbers are to be achieved.
This approach deserves to be explained in more detail.
Chart 1 describes some of the main macroeconomic indicators
of the previous two Plan periods. Average annual GDP
growth in the Tenth Plan is estimated to be 7 per cent,
below the plan target of 8 per cent but still above
the annual rate of any previous Plan period.
Chart
1 >>
However,
certain features of this growth process need to be noted.
First, this respectable average rate of growth resulted
from a combination of poor performance in agriculture
and improved performance in the other two sectors. More
significantly, it was associated with not just higher
investment rates but significantly higher savings rates,
which in the event have turned out to be higher than
investment rates. This is why the current account has
actually been in surplus over the Plan period, at an
average of 0.7 per cent of GDP.
This
needs to be compared with the projections of the Tenth
Plan, as shown in Chart 2. It is evident from this that
even if the Tenth Plan had approximated the aggregate
rates of investment and growth, its projections of the
structure of that growth have been completely belied.
Thus, agriculture in particular has performed well below
target. Most surprisingly, however, the savings rate
has been well above target while the investment rate
has nevertheless been below target! This is why the
GDP growth has been associated with current account
surplus rather than deficit.
Chart
2 >>
But
it points to a very disturbing feature of the past growth,
which is that over the Tenth Plan, the investment rate
has fallen well below the potential provided by the
domestic savings rate as well as a feasible current
account deficit. In other words, investment has seriously
underperformed.
In
any reasonable planning exercise, surely the first question
following upon this should be: why has this happened?
Of course, to take investment and growth alone as the
basic macroeconomic targets is deeply problematic, as
we shall discuss below. But if they are to be taken
as targets, then it is incumbent upon the planners to
assess the past performance and consider why the outcomes
were so different from those that were expected. And
the answer to this question should at least inform the
strategy for the next plan.
Thus, one major difference between the anticipated and
actual in the indicators, which has contributed to the
final outcome, is the much lower rate of public investment.
This has been only around 7 per cent of GDP compared
to the Tenth Plan target of 8.4 per cent. This has critically
affected not only the aggregate investment rate but
also private investment, since there are well known
synergies between public and private investment. And
the relatively inadequate performance of public investment
is related to the misplaced perceptions of fiscal constraint
that have prevented the government from increasing much
needed public investment despite favourable macroeconomic
conditions.
This has been marked for both direct public investment
(the ''capital expenditure'' of the government) and investment
of Public Sector Enterprises, many of whom currently
hold their profits as reserves or to provide savings
for use by government and private sectors rather than
being encouraged to engage in active expansion and investment
themselves. Indeed, the inadequate investment by PSEs,
amounting to a huge waste of public assets as well as
enormous unutilised investment potential, was a major
crime of omission of the previous NDA government that
has thus far been continued by the UPA government. This
is worth remembering every time the central government
cries wolf about the shortage of resources available
for public investment, and argues that FDI is the only
alternative to generate growth or, even worse, when
it divests its own shares in cash rich PSUs and claims
that the proceeds will increase public investment.
This past and current practice of inadequate public
sector investment (by both government and PSEs) in turn
has already had adverse implications for the future.
As Table 1 indicates, even the Planning Commission's
own projections essentially show PSE profits (and therefore
savings out of profits) as more or less constant as
GDP increases, such that a higher rate of GDP growth
is actually associated with a lower contribution of
PSE savings.
Table
1 >>
This
in turn creates more pressure on government savings,
such that the government is forced into an even more
contractionary fiscal stance in these projected growth
scenarios, and moving from dissaving to positive saving
amounting to 2.4 per cent of GDP in the highest growth
scenario.
This
is actually a travesty of the idea of public sector
involvement in a developing economy, since it takes
the government sector and public sector enterprises
away from being net investors to being net savers and
providers of resources for private investment. Since
there are many areas where private investment will continue
to be lacking or socially sub-optimal, because of externalities
and social returns being higher than private expected
returns, that means that all such areas will be underprovided.
These include critical areas such as infrastructure,
health, sanitation and education, and so on. Yet, amazingly,
the Planning Commission actually appears to be envisaging
such a scenario in future.
This self-imposed constraint upon crucial public expenditure
is one of the chief macroeconomic drawbacks of the Approach
Paper. The government may argue that the Fiscal Responsibility
and Budget Management Act has left it no choice but
to bring fiscal and revenue deficits down to the targets
specified in the Act. But the FRBMA has actually become
an unnecessary millstone around the government's neck,
preventing it from undertaking necessary expenditures
to improve the condition of citizens and to ensure a
desirable pattern of growth.
The Approach Paper's section on financing the public
sector plan does indeed recognise some of the difficulties
posed by the rigid and indeed unreasonable demands of
the FRBMA, and even suggests a postponement of the targets
for fiscal and revenue deficits, by a period of two
years. But the more plausible argument, of course, is
simply that this Act should be scrapped by the same
Parliament that chose to bring it in, because it is
illogical, puts bizarre constraints on necessary and
desirable revenue spending, does not allow anti-cyclical
fiscal stances and also - as apparently recognised here
by the Planning Commission - militates against higher
economic growth.
However, the more pertinent question in this context
relates to the growth obsession that is evident in much
of the document. In this Approach Paper, the lack of
realism or even awareness of recent national and international
experience in this regard is evident. The simplistic
and discredited ''trickle down'' argument is assumed to
operate in its more benign and dynamic form, despite
all evidence to the contrary. This completely belies
the very title of the document - which suggests that
the government wants to move towards more inclusive
growth - since there is no consideration of changes
in the pattern of growth that would be required to make
it more inclusive.
The most critical aspect of growth that determines whether
it is more ''inclusive'' is the extent to which it generates
productive employment. This is where growth in India
has been so lacking in the past fifteen years, since
agrarian crisis combined with lack of adequate employment
generation in other sectors have been the primary causes
for the inequalising growth process so far. Yet, in
the listing of the major challenges facing the government
at the start of the document, there is no mention of
employment generation!
Further, there is no concern with ensuring that the
pattern of growth will be such as to generate more employment,
or ideas about how to go about this. Instead, as will
be described in the next edition of MacroScan, several
policy initiatives suggested (such as liberalising the
entry of foreign players into retail trade) would actually
damage employment among small retailers and petty traders
even further, rather than increase it.
Similarly, the other great economic challenge facing
the country at present - the agrarian crisis reflected
in high and unsustainable levels of peasant debt and
the lack of viability of cultivation because of the
cost-price relationship for many crops - is barely considered
in this document. The Plan projections blithely assume
(Table 1) that GDP in agriculture will grow much faster
than it has done for the past decade, yet suggests no
ways to ensure this. It is simply assumed that diversification
into horticulture (which is not feasible for most dryland
areas) and contract farming will automatically generate
much higher income growth from agriculture. There is
no discussion of any planned and systematic state intervention
to address the structural and conjunctural forces currently
devastating crop production.
In general therefore, the macroeconomic presumptions
of the approach are faulty and unlikely to generate
anything resembling more inclusive growth. Several other
features of the proposed approach, which will be discussed
in the next edition of MacroScan, are likely to lead
to greater economic exclusion and more fragile economic
circumstances for millions of people. The Approach Paper
is particularly worrying because it suggests that even
the Planning Commission, which is the agency within
the government that is charged with the task of looking
ahead and thinking strategically about the economy,
has no intention of doing so.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|