The alternative possibility
is that the government will bring down the APL wheat price to around
Rs 700 per quintal all over the country. This would encourage sales
through fair price shops, and also increase the overall offtake (through
both PDS and OMSS) quite sharply, taking these to about 10-20 per cent
above last year's level, as against a decline in the previous scenario.
But, even in this scenario, wheat stocks on April 1, 2001 would be around
17 million tonnes, so that, although the pressure on storage capacity
will be much reduced on that date, the available storage capacity is
unlikely to allow for wheat procurement in excess of 11-12 million tonnes.
On the other hand, since the cost of grain at the current MSP of Rs
580 per quintal is at least Rs 675 per quintal, inclusive of statutory
charges and the cost of gunny, the private trade will stay away from
purchases unless this is possible below MSP or can be effected without
paying the statutory dues. As a result, the public agencies will be
faced with having to buy almost the entire arrival in mandies, and since
farmers turned away due to the shortage of storage space will almost
certainly receive much less than the current MSP, the credibility of
that system would be under severe threat.
Thus, the nation may now be
at a brink where the very future of India's existing food security system
may be at stake. This has so far depended on MSP purchases to stabilise
producer prices and on PDS offtake to stabilise consumer prices, and,
in this, it has been fairly successful since the variability of foodgrain
prices in India have so far been less than a third of what it is in
international markets. The problem has to do not only with the high
MSP levels which have pushed up procurement, but also with the Targeted
Public Distribution System (TPDS). This was adopted in 1997 in an effort
to target the food subsidy towards the poor, and the subsequent increases
in Central Issue Prices were made with a view to contain the overall
food subsidy bill. It now appears that it has failed in both these objectives.
The reduced allocations and higher APL prices under TPDS has pushed
the food subsidy bill to an all-time high because of sharply increased
stock holding costs. Simultaneously, these stocks have pushed up open
market prices of cereals by almost 30 per cent in the three years that
the TPDS has existed, hurting precisely the poor who were sought to
be served but who still have to buy more than half their grain requirements
from the open market.
Also, the main objective of
the original PDS was to contain inter-temporal and inter-regional differentials
in retail consumer prices arising either from high trade and transport
costs or because of local monopolies. This aspect of price stabilisation,
which is best served not through open market sales to millers but through
sales actually effected at local fair price shops, depends vitally on
the financial viability of the existing network of over 4 lakh fair
price shops. This, too, is now under threat because their sales have
shrunk sharply as a result of the effective exclusion of APL families
under TPDS.
Most ominously, with procurement
currently exceeding the reduced TPDS offtake by a large margin, there
are already demands in the press, and from certain economists close
to the World Bank and IMF who were incidentally instrumental in the
adoption of the TPDS, that the system of Minimum Price Support itself
be wound up. But the MSP system, which protects farmers from undue price
fluctuation, has been a crucial part of the package of policies which
has enabled Indian farmers to multiply cereal production by over two
and a half times since the mid-sixties, and thus avert the possibility
of growing hunger.
The demands to give up this
system up are coming at a time when not only has the rate of growth
of domestic foodgrain production dropped below the rate of population
growth so that the long-term vulnerability to food security has increased,
but also when, as a result of more open trade, all Indian farmers, not
just rice and wheat producers, are faced with the prospect of much higher
price volatility and increased unfair competition from their highly
subsidised counterparts in the West.
Interestingly also, the very
economists who today castigate politicians and farm interests most loudly
for pushing up the MSP too high are precisely those who till recently
had argued most strongly that Indian farm prices were too low in relation
to the world price, and that accepting the WTO discipline would bring
even greater benefits in the form of even higher world prices. It is
another matter that these economists were proved totally wrong since
world agricultural prices actually collapsed between 1997 and 1999 when
this argument had reached its crescendo. But can these economists honestly
absolve themselves of responsibility, since their misguided analysis
may actually have been taken seriously by those who allowed the MSPs
in India to ratchet upwards from peaks reached by the world prices just
when these had begun to turn sharply downwards ?
Thus, whether the MSP levels
are correct, whether targeting is consistent with stable stock levels,
or whether higher issue prices will be successful in reducing the food
subsidy in the face of increasing stocks, are all questions which appear
to have failed most mainstream economists wedded to unthinking liberalisation.
So what is the solution if one does not accept the view that the present
food security system should be given up since a combination of free
trade and futures markets will necessarily bring panacea for an Indian
agriculture dominated by small and financially vulnerable farmers ?
On this, the only sensible argument in government seems to have come
from that organisation which is directly concerned with the matter but
to which nobody seems to listen nowadays - the Commission on Agricultural
Costs and Prices.
In the Commission's Reports
for Rabi crops sown during 1999-2000 season, it had argued strongly
that primacy be placed on balancing procurement and offtake in the medium
run. It noted that such a balance could be reached with different combinations
of procurement and issue prices but that if the former was high, and
led to high procurement, the latter should be correspondingly low to
ensure high enough offtake, even though this would involve a relatively
high subsidy. Attempting to hike the issue prices without cutting the
procurement price in this situation would be counterproductive since
not only would the subsidy rise further in the short run, it would make
the system unstable.
It noted further that the only
viable way of reducing the subsidy was by choosing a lower ratio of
the MSP to cost, and that once a decision was taken on this, reconciling
the inherent conflict between a high MSP and a low subsidy level, the
MSP itself should be defended against international price fluctuations
through a system whereby tariffs on exports and imports were automatically
varied with movements in world prices. The only way to get out of the
present mess, according to this analysis, is to have a temporary moratorium
on the MSP for wheat, keeping issue prices at the level required to
maintain medium run balance between procurement and offtake. This would,
however, still leave the problem of the existing large stocks built
up over the last few years, but these should be treated as investible
resources to build up infrastructure through food for work programmes.
To this very sensible analysis,
which has of course been ignored until now, it may be added that in
the short run it may now be necessary to use some of the food for work
programmes to build godowns immediately, in order to ensure that rats
do not get the first bite again.
|