In sum,
the post-1996 evidence pointing to a slowing of import
growth despite liberalisation provides little cause
for comfort. It by no means suggests that there is no
relationship between liberalisation and import flows.
Rather it suggests that signs of a strong positive relationship
during the 1993-94 to 1995-96 period was diluted by
lower oil prices, by a recession in industry and by
a fall in the unit value indices of imports. The decline
in oil prices has been dramatically reversed over the
last year. Recession is too high a price to pay to sustain
a viable trade deficit. And as and when world growth
revives and transnational firms get a foothold in the
domestic market, unit value indices would turn firm.
All this is of special concern because, despite these
"benefits", export performance has been so
poor that the trade deficit has tended to widen precisely
in the years of slower import growth (Chart 2). The
Commerce Minister has argued that it is this problem,
rather than US pressure to do away with QRs, that his
exim policy announcement has sought to address. However,
it hardly bears stating that the "new" measures
announced amount to little more than mere rhetoric.
Besides further minor changes in import procedures,
the only initiatives incorporated in the announcement
is the creation of a set of "special economic zones"
inspired by the Chinese experience and the decision
to provide incentives to the states to help contribute
to the export effort.
Chart
2 >> Click
to Enlarge
The special economic zones are to be export enclaves
into which duty free imports are to be permitted and
in which foreign investors are permitted to set up firms
with up to 100 per cent equity holding. In practice
this would merely amount to the creation of larger sized
free trade zones, as is reflected in the fact that two
such proposed FTZs are to be converted in SEZs. Past
experience with the free trade zones has been dismal.
And with growing liberalisation of trade and rules governing
foreign investment, the distinction between firms located
in such special zones and those operating out of the
domestic tariff area have been increasingly diluted.
Above all, what this initiative assumes is that an export
drive has to be FDI driven. The expectation is that
India should not just attract foreign direct investment,
but relocative FDI, which chooses India as a site for
world market-oriented production. In practice, foreign
investors have hitherto contributed little to the export
effort and in many cases have not even met their export
commitments under schemes such as the Export Promotion
Capital Goods Scheme, which permits capital imports
on concession terms in return for a promise to meet
certain export targets. Further, if we examine the kind
of FDI flow into India in the wake of liberalisation,
we find that it consists of three types: that which
has come in to increase the equity stake of the foreign
partner in exiting joint ventures from the 40 per cent
level mandated by FERA to levels up to 100 per cent
permitted in the wake of liberalisation; second, that
which has come to acquire India firms with a large share
of the market in certain products, a case epitomised
by the acquisition of Parle by Coca Cola; and third,
that which has come into the infrastructural (non-tradable)
sector, in response to the generous concessions offered
by the government. It should be clear that a lot of
these inflows are not even into greenfield projects
and all of them are targeted at the domestic rather
than the export market. There is no reason to expect
a shift from such FDI inflows to more export-oriented
flows in the current world environment, where internationally
competitive capacities can be acquired at bargain prices
in East Asian countries going through a "restructuring"
process. In fact, what is likely is that even FDI targeted
at the domestic market would shrink, as happened last
financial year, since post-liberalisation that market
can be serviced with imports from abroad. |