Putting the matter differently, if under a controlled
regime there is surreptitious outflow of finance capital, it does not
follow that the removal of controls, merely by legalising financial
outflows, would eliminate them. On the contrary, such legalisation would
merely compound the problem, and squeezing the poor in the economy and
destroying its extant productive base in the hope of building up the
"confidence" of international creditors and potential direct
foreign investors, would merely amount to chasing a chimera.
The second strategy which is quite different
from the above, though the difference is usually glossed over by the
proponents of the above, is a strategy of neo-mercantilism, such as
has been followed in many East Asian countries, notably South Korea.
Here we do not have a move towards "free trade" and the "free
market"; the State remains highly interventionist though the nature
and mode of intervention from what prevailed over much of the Third
World earlier; the entry of imports into the economy is controlled,
as is the capital account of the balance of payments; at the same time,
strenuous efforts are made, under State patronage, to push out as much
of exports as possible (which is why the term "neo-mercantilism"
is so apposite); the sheer magnitude of export growth enables the economy
to borrow from abroad, not for financing indiscriminate import liberalisation,
but for stepping up the investment ratio; this together with very high
domestic savings rates permits the maintenance of phenomenal investment
rates, which in turn lead to such impressive growth rates as contribute
to the maintenance of foreign creditors' confidence.
Much has been written by way of analysis of
this strategy: about the nature of the State that can be so interventionist
without being "dirigiste" in the old sense, about the necessity
of land reforms as a pre-condition for such a strategy, about the role
of near-universal literacy in making this strategy a success, and so
on, and we need not repeat all that here. But there are at least two
factors which put a question mark on the viability of this strategy,
and these deserve a discussion. The first of these is the international
context. There can be little doubt that for such a neo-mercantilist
strategy to succeed, there has to be a deliberate policy in other countries,
especially the advanced countries, of accommodating exports from these
countries. The neo-mercantilist policy pursued by Germany around the
turn of the century was so successful because other countries, notably
Britain which was interested in preserving the Gold Standard, were willing
to absorb large amounts of German exports. Like- wise, the post-war
Japanese miracle could not have occurred, if the United States, for
strategic reasons (having to do with the containment of Communism) had
not provided such substantial market access to Japanese exports. And
the same can be said of the other successful East Asian countries.
The second problem relates to internal opposition.
A neo- mercantilist strategy is necessarily associated with a degree
of suppression of workers' rights, a shift in income distribution against
the working class and in favour of business profits, and, in a large
economy, a growth in regional disparities. All these are difficult to
accommodate within a framework of representative democracy. Such a strategy
therefore, no less than the Fund-Bank strategy, is associated with bureaucratic-authoritarian
forms of government. This however only suppresses internal opposition
but does not reduce the degree of its hostility. In a society where
the legitimacy of governance is founded upon the legacy of a revolutionary
struggle, or even of a mass anti-colonial struggle, such an economic
strategy runs the serious risk of succumbing to an internal upheaval.
Moreover whether or not it so succumbs, one can legitimately question
the desirability of any strategy that requires for its success the suppression
of workers' rights, and hence, by implication, of democratic rights
in general. And finally, since "outward orientation" (though
of a neo- mercantilist sort) is an essential component of this strategy,
its viability in the context of the emerging world capitalist recession
is open to serious doubt.
The question which immediately arises is: does
an alternative viable economic strategy exist for the Third World, which,
while not taking us back to the earlier "dirigisme", can avoid
both the Fund-Bank trap, as well as the temptations of an authoritarian
neo-mercantilism. In one sense of course the question is absurd, though
in another sense it is not. Economic strategies are not chosen like
one chooses a shirt or a pair of socks; they emerge out of a complex
social reality, and reflect the interplay of different classes and social
groups within that reality. So the question is not one of picking out
some sort of an optimal strategy. Nonetheless a discussion of possibilities,
whether or not they realise themselves, does constitute an important
intellectual task. Before we can even think of changing the world, we
should have some preliminary idea of the direction in which we should
be changing it.
The main problem highlighted above, namely the
outflow of finance from the Third World in an international economy
characterised by great capital fluidity, derives its strength from one
basic fact mentioned above: given the pattern of income distribution
and tastes in the Third World country, there is a wide divergence between
the extant structure of production and the structure of demand, and
this divergence is never bridged. This necessarily means a one-way flow
of innovations: the Third World is all the time trying to catch up in
the production of those commodities which are currently being produced
in the metropolitan countries and for which a demand exists within the
Third World as well. This perpetual product cycle, in which the Third
World is lagging behind the metropolitan countries, is the primary cause
of the pressure on its external payments, which gets compounded by the
fluidity of capital mentioned above.
To get out of this syndrome, while controls
over imports and over the capital account of the balance of payments
are essential, they are obviously insufficient. There has to be a sufficient
growth of exports. While the relentless export drive characteristic
of neo-mercantilism need not be endorsed, there is no gainsaying the
fact that most "dirigiste" regimes earlier tended implicitly
to discriminate against exporting. This anti- export bias is counterproductive.
Export-led growth, which, whether the proponents of the Fund-Bank strategy
admit or not, is logically inherent as the central thrust of their strategy,
offers no solution to the Third World; but pushing out sufficient exports
inter alia to ensure that the balance of payments are not put to undue
strain is essential for any development programme.
At a more fundamental level however the need
is to break out of the grip of this peculiar product cycle. Greater
equality in the pattern of asset and income distribution is a necessary
condition for this, since the ex-ante demand for metropolitan goods
per unit of income is likely to be greater for the upper income groups
than for the poor. This calls not just for the use of the fiscal instrument,
but for a reorientation of the development strategy. Land reforms, the
provision of minimum employment and basic amenities, health and education
facilities, the development of rural infrastructure etc. must take precedence
over the setting up of large import-intensive projects on the basis
of borrowed technology with negligible employment-generating effect
upon the domestic economy.
Income redistribution alone however would be
insufficient. In the long-run there is no getting away from the need
for a change in tastes and a self-liberation, not a State-imposed one,
from the culture of Western-style consumerism. This is not to argue
for a turning of one's back upon modern technology, but for a selectivity
in the import of technology and an effort at an independent trajectory
of innovations.
For all this of course the role of the State
is absolutely essential, but as the experience of the earlier "dirigiste"
regimes suggests, it is equally essential to enforce accountability
of the State. This of course is a big issue in itself. But the need
for accountability is by no means obviated, as is often erroneously
thought, by the mere substitution of a "market-friendly" economic
regime for a "dirigiste" economic regime. Perhaps the very
alteration in the development strategy suggested above, with greater
emphasis upon the immediate provision of better living standards for
the poor, would throw up new institutions (for more decentralised decision-making)
as well as new levels of consciousness and popular participation that
would make greater accountability of the State a meaningful reality.
Notwithstanding the constraints imposed by the
international economy there exists a path of sustainable democratic
development for the Third World. But the combination of social forces
required for arriving at this path and remaining on or near it is not
easy to organise.