|
|
|
|
Measuring
Progress
|
|
Sep
30th 2009, Jayati Ghosh |
|
For
some time now it has been clear that standard measurements
of growth and development are inadequate and possibly
even misleading. The problem of looking at only the
aggregate gross domestic product (GDP) has been widely
noted: its blindness to distributional issues and its
inability to measure either the quality of life or the
sustainability of any particular system of production,
distribution and consumption. Despite these obvious
limitations, however, the GDP remains the most widely
used indicator of any economy and is generally the benchmark
used to determine both performance and policy orientations
of most governments.
The more wide-ranging human development index, or HDI,
(which is the simple average of income measured by the
GDP, health measured by life expectancy and education
measured by literacy/enrolment) is clearly superior
to the simple per capita GDP indicator. It is particularly
useful because it often provides rankings of economies
that are quite different from those based purely on
per capita income. Nevertheless, even the HDI is increasingly
being viewed as limited because it does not fully capture
the complex relationships between current levels of
income and growth, basic health and education indicators,
and quality of life.
Several recent economic processes have made the need
to search for alternative indicators of human well-being
even more pressing. The global financial and economic
crisis has exposed the problems and contradictions inherent
in the earlier boom, which were not recognised by the
wider public even though they were certainly discussed
among a segment of largely unnoticed economists. Meanwhile,
climate change and other evidence of ecological damage
have highlighted how fragile and eventually unsustainable
current patterns of economic activity are. And the distributional
issues that were swept under the carpet in the age of
dominant finance and resurgent capital are becoming
prominent once again.
These may be what prompted President Nicolas Sarkozy
of France (whom some may otherwise have considered to
be an unlikely candidate for alternative economic thinking)
to set up a commission in the middle of last year to
deliberate alternative measures of economic and social
progress. The commission has Joseph Stiglitz as chair,
Amartya Sen as chair adviser and Jean-Paul Fitoussi
as coordinator and an impressive list of economists
and social scientists from across the world as its members.
The commission has now submitted its report, ''Report
by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance
and Social Progress'', available at http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/documents/rapport_anglais.pdf.
The commission's terms of reference were nothing if
not sweeping: ''To identify the limits of GDP as an indicator
of economic performance and social progress, including
the problems with its measurement; to consider what
additional information might be required for the production
of more relevant indicators of social progress; to assess
the feasibility of alternative measurement tools, and
to discuss how to present the statistical information
in an appropriate way.''
These are huge issues, and not only because of the philosophical
and methodological concerns they raise. The empirical
and statistical issues may well present the greater
challenge. After all, one of the reasons for the continued
domination of the GDP as the basic measure despite its
many limitations is its apparent simplicity and ease
of availability across countries and time periods. This
is also why the HDI remains the most popular alternative
measure. Any new measure will have to confront the basic
problem of providing correct insights on the basis of
readily available data across different countries and
time periods.
For this reason, the commission's report was eagerly
awaited in the hope that it would provide some feasible
alternatives that could be used and disseminated and
that it would provide both alternative measures for
analysts as well as alternative goals for policymakers.
However, while the report makes a number of useful and
often profound points, it may have failed to fulfil
this most urgent of goals. Instead, it seems designed
to open up a discussion, thereby leaving some of the
most crucial questions unanswered.
The report notes that there often seems to be a marked
distance between the standard measures of important
socio-economic variables, such as economic growth, inflation
and unemployment, and public perceptions about them.
It accepts that these differences are often too large
and persistent to be simply attributed to money illusion
or similar features. Instead, it notes that these differences
can arise from flawed measurement processes, inadequate
concepts, income distribution effects or because the
measures do not capture other phenomena or features
that affect well-being. It recognises that conceptual
issues and socio-economic inequalities are particularly
important.
Therefore, the report advocates a shift of emphasis
from a ''production-oriented'' measurement system to one
focussed on the well-being of current and future generations.
This in turn means shifting from measuring economic
production to measuring people's well-being in an overall
context of sustainability. This means that when evaluating
material well-being it is necessary to look at income
and consumption rather than production; to emphasise
the household perspective including unpaid labour; to
consider income and consumption jointly with wealth;
to give more prominence to the distribution of income,
consumption and wealth; and to broaden income measures
to non-market activities.
The last is a complex and potentially controversial
matter. Non-market activities constitute a significant
part of both production and consumption in many societies,
and the gender dimension of this is well known. The
lack of recognition and social reward for such activities
has also been identified as a major problem. However,
including some valuation of such activities in estimates
of income may have the perverse effect of increasing
the estimated incomes of households and societies that
are currently perceived as poor. In other words, the
presence of a high proportion of non-market activities,
which are associated with lack of development and greater
poverty, may well become a false indicator of better
living conditions and thereby do the poor (and women
who typically perform a greater part of such non-monetised
activities) a double disservice.
In other areas, the conclusions of the commission are
certainly not objectionable, but since they are expressed
in a general way, they appear to be somewhat banal.
Thus, the report states that well-being is multidimensional
and includes not only material living standards (such
as income, consumption and wealth) but also health,
education, personal activities including work, political
voice and governance, social connections and relationships,
present and future conditions of the environment, and
physical and economic security.
This in turn means that quality of life depends not
only on people's objective conditions and capabilities
but also on their subjective perceptions of life satisfaction.
The report argues that statistical offices should incorporate
questions to capture people's life evaluations, hedonic
experiences and priorities in their own surveys. This
is something that has already been attempted by the
new economics foundation (nef), London, which recently
produced an extremely interesting ''Happy Planet Index''
(HPI), which uses survey-based data on life satisfaction
in addition to other ''hard'' variables to arrive at the
index as follows:
HPI = (Life expectancy X Life satisfaction)/Ecological
footprint.
(According to this index, Costa Rica emerges as the
''happiest'' country, with the United States and several
other rich countries rather low down in the list.) However,
unlike the HPI, the commission's report does not really
present very clear methodological answers on how to
go about taking both life satisfaction and hard variables
into consideration. Similarly, because the commission
recognises the critical role of inequalities, its report
notes that quality-of-life indicators in all the dimensions
covered should assess inequalities in a comprehensive
way. This is certainly desirable but does not provide
a useful alternative measure that would incorporate
inequalities in a feasible way.
Similarly, the issues of measuring sustainability and
environmental indicators are also effectively side-stepped.
According to the report, ''Sustainability assessment
requires a well-identified dashboard of indicators.
The distinctive feature of the components of this dashboard
should be that they are interpretable as variations
of some underlying 'stocks'. A monetary index of sustainability
has its place in such a dashboard but, under the current
state of the art, it should remain essentially focussed
on economic aspects of sustainability. The environmental
aspects of sustainability deserve a separate follow-up
based on a well-chosen set of physical indicators. In
particular there is a need for a clear indicator of
our proximity to dangerous levels of environmental damage
(such as associated with climate change or the depletion
of fishing stocks.)''
Once again, this is too general to be really useful.
In that sense, the commission has not really been able
to provide a conceptual or measurement breakthrough
even along the lines of the HDI. It is not surprising
that one is left asking for more. The authors of the
report seem to be aware of this. In a closing section,
they note: ''The commission regards its report as opening
a discussion rather than closing it.'' But this discussion
has been open, and indeed ongoing, for quite a while,
even if not in the rarefied corridors of mainstream
economics. The commission must be credited for contributing
sensibly and wisely to the existing global conversation
on this important matter but cannot be congratulated
for making any new advances.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|