|
|
|
|
Employment
Generation as an Economic Strategy for Uncertain Times*
|
|
Nov
14th 2011, Jayati Ghosh |
|
It is truly a great honour for me to receive this award,
and I am especially deeply honoured to be part of the
broader agenda that the ILO has been pursuing, which
I believe is especially critical in the current fragile
global economic environment. I believe that the ILO
can make an important contribution to a new direction,
based on the generation of decent work as the fundamental
goal, which can even become a game-changing approach
to macroeconomic strategy.
Any formulation of economic strategy for our times must
rest on some increasingly evident current realities:
periods of ''rapid growth'' have been based on unsustainable
bubbles; such growth has contributed little in terms
of generating more decent work and has significantly
increased inequality; and popular sentiment is now against
accepting these outcomes as reflected in the waves of
protest in many different countries. This requires a
completely different approach to macroeconomic policy
making, which will be more compatible with the increasingly
more vocally expressed aspirations and expectations
of citizens.
Global uncertainties
The global economy is now in uncharted waters. The two
largest economic entities – the US and the European
Union – are clearly in economic conditions that will
prevent their being positive engines for global growth
for some time. The continuing crisis in the eurozone
is unfortunately unlikely to be quickly resolved with
any of the proposals that are currently on the table.
Meanwhile in the United States, there appears to be
inadequate political appetite for the policies that
would ensure a more sustained recovery. Expectations
that China or developing Asia in general can become
an alternative growth pole immediately to take up the
slack are unwarranted, given the relative size of these
economies and their continued export dependence on the
US and the EU.
Two major misreadings of economic policy requirements
have combined to intensify the ongoing global crisis.
The first is the notion that the immediate concern is
the reduction of public debt and reduction of fiscal
deficits. In fact, worsening fiscal imbalances in most
major economies were a result of the 2008 financial
crisis, not a cause of it, as automatic stabilizers
and fiscal stimulus packages came into play. In the
developed world (including now troubled economies like
Ireland and Spain) public bailouts accounted for a large
part of the deficit, as private bad debts were taken
into public hands. The median public debt to GDP ratio
in developed countries almost doubled (to more than
60 per cent of GDP) between 2007 and 2010.
It is already evident that fiscal tightening in stressed
economies is self-defeating. By reducing GDP growth
and thereby fiscal revenues, it makes economic recovery
more difficult and is counterproductive in terms of
improving fiscal indicators. It is difficult if not
impossible to reduce debt to GDP ratios in a period
when the rate of interest on debt far exceeds the nominal
growth rate. Further, the fact that surplus countries
show no willingness to reduce surpluses or enlarge deficit
bodes ill for global growth prospects. What will drive
growth – globally and nationally - when countries (even
those with external surpluses) persist in following
austerity programmes that cut incomes and demand?
The second major misreading is an over-optimistic assessment
of the self-correcting powers of financial markets.
It has meant that thus far attempts to re-regulate of
financial markets have been limited and halting. Financial
deregulation led to a large, opaque and undercapitalized
''shadow banking system''. It increased concentration
in the traditional banking segment in a few ''too big
to fail'' institutions and increased systemic risk.
Post-crisis, governments' lender-of-last-resort support
to the financial system has even extended to the shadow
banking system, creating massively increased moral hazard.
Global commodity markets have also been affected by
financial speculation, causing food and fuel prices
to spiral with grave consequences for people across
the world. This context makes strong re-regulation of
finance urgent and essential. Controls have to be tighter
on the ''too-big-to-fail'' institutions; cover the ''shadow
banking'' institutions so to avoid regulatory arbitrage;
and incorporate a macro-prudential dimension, with anti-cyclical
capital requirements and capital controls. But re-regulation
alone will not orient credit to real investment or make
it accessible to small and medium-sized firms. So there
must be restructuring of the financial system: giant
institutions must be downsized; the activities of commercial
and investment banking should be clearly separated,
in order to reduce the risk of contagion; and the aim
should be more diverse financial systems, with a bigger
role for public and cooperative institutions. Commodity
markets, which have been subject to wild price swings
related to speculative and herd behaviour, need to be
made more transparent, with controls on financial activity
in these markets and direct intervention when required
to curb price bubbles and prevent sharp declines.
Limitations of the dominant economic strategy
However, it is not just the crisis that has emphasised
the urgent need for a shift in economic strategy. The
need for a major reconsideration of macroeconomic strategies
is even evident in the experience of the previous boom
and of the performance of ''successful'' economies.
Recent economic growth has been associated with and
even depended upon the greater power of capital (both
multinational and domestic), reflected in rising shares
of profit and interest in national income. Governments
have not seen higher wages, more employment and better
conditions as economic policy priorities, but rather
as eventual by-products of the growth process. Unfortunately,
in many economies, income growth has not necessarily
been accompanied by more decent work. Also, this profit-led
growth is not sustainable beyond a point, as has become
increasingly evident in the past few years.
The export-driven model of growth has come to be seen
as the most successful strategy, driven by the success
of China and Germany in particular. The model, sought
to be emulated by almost all developing countries, was
associated with suppressing wage costs and domestic
consumption in the attempt to remain internationally
competitive and increase shares of global markets. Managing
exchange rates to remain competitive, despite either
current account surpluses or capital inflows, was a
central element of this strategy. This was associated
with the peculiar situation of rising savings rates
and falling investment rates in many developing countries,
and to the holding of international reserves that were
then sought to be placed in safe assets abroad. This
is a classic dilemma of a mercantilist strategy: such
economies are forced to finance the deficits of those
countries that would buy their products, through capital
flows that sustain the demand for their own exports,
even when those countries have significantly higher
per capita income than their own.
The strategy also generated fewer jobs than a more labour-intensive
pattern based on expanding domestic demand would have
done, which meant that employment increased relatively
little despite often dramatic rises in aggregate output.
This is why globally the previous boom was associated
with the South subsidising the North: through cheaper
exports of goods and services, through net capital flows
from developing countries to the US in particular, through
flows of cheap labour in the form of short-term migration.
Despite the current fragile recovery, such a strategy
is unsustainable beyond a point, especially when a number
of relatively large economies seek to use it at the
same time. This strategy bred and increased global inequality,
and also sowed the seeds of its own destruction for
both external and internal reasons. Externally, deficit
countries will either choose or be forced to reduce
their deficits through various means, including protectionist
responses. Internally, suppression of wage incomes and
domestic consumption will meet with political resistance.
In either case, the pressures to find more sustainable
sources of economic growth, particularly through domestic
demand and wage-led alternatives, are likely to increase.
So countries must diversify their sources of growth,
looking for other export markets as well as for internal
engines of growth. This is what makes arguments for
a shift in strategy towards domestic wage- and employment-led
growth so compelling.
The current crisis as opportunity for change
in economic strategy
This is a historic opportunity to move away from the
single-minded obsession with GDP growth delivered by
large private corporate actors, towards feasible economic
development trajectories that are more just and democratic.
This is no doubt a challenging task, but it is now essential.
The critical shift required is most of all in terms
of orientation. It is important not to see the generation
of decent work simply as a potential positive by-product
of income growth, but as a means to sustainable growth,
as well as an end in itself. This approach relies on
strong positive multiplier effects to create virtuous
cycles of employment and productivity growth. It allows
for more stable economic growth that is based on expanding
the domestic market, but it does not need to conflict
with increasing exports. It encourages a greater emphasis
on aggregate productivity growth (rather than only through
cutting-edge new technologies), thereby generating a
''high road'' to industrialization from the bottom.
Thus, a focus on generating more decent work can actually
become a competitive advantage rather than allowing
fear of global competition to generate a race to the
bottom in labour standards.
In developed countries with relatively strong institutions
that can affect the labour market, including collective
wage bargaining, effective minimum wage legislation
and the like, it is probably easier to think of wage-led
growth and strategies to allow wages to keep pace (or
at least grow to some extent) along with labour productivity
growth. But what about most developing countries, where
such institutions are relatively poorly developed and
where many of not most workers are in informal activities,
often self-employed? How are wage increases and better
working conditions to be ensured in such cases? And
what does a macroeconomic policy of wage-led growth
entail in such a context?
In fact, such a strategy is also possible in economies
with large informal sectors, through policies that increase
the availability of consumer goods, basic services and
various forms of social protection, and also improve
the viability of small-scale production. Employment
diversification, in terms of a long term sustained shift
of workers away from low productivity (largely primary
sector) activities to activities with higher productivity
and value added, has long been seen as a central aspect
of development. The growth of good quality wage employment
in both the public and private sectors is central to
the diversification process. In addition, the conditions
of self-employment have to be improved, made less insecure
and fragile and with excessive burdens of risk that
are hard to bear for small producers.
There are several important elements of such a wage-
and employment-led strategy in most developing countries.
First of all, the focus of macroeconomic policies must
be on the generation of decent work and on improving
conditions of life, not on income growth per se. This
is important because it makes the provision of basic
needs (employment as well as access to food, sanitation,
housing, health and education) and improving the quality
of life of all citizens the central guiding principles.
Quantitative GDP growth targets, that still tend to
dominate the thinking of policy makers, are not simply
distracting from these more important goals, but can
even be counterproductive. For example, a chaotic, polluting
and unpleasant system of privatised urban transport
involving many private vehicles and over-congested roads
actually generates more GDP than a safe, efficient,
affordable and ''green'' system of public transport
that reduces vehicular congestion and provides a pleasant
living and working environment.
Second, it is necessary to ensure the greater viability
of informal and small-scale production, through better
access to institutional credit to farmers and other
small producers (including through directed credit,
subsidies etc.), greater integration into supply chains
and marketing that improves their returns, focus on
co-operative arrangements that can provide the benefits
of scale economies to small producers and technology
improvements that increase labour productivity in such
activities. It is particularly important to be aware
of the specific needs of women producers and workers
in informal activities when designing policies. Such
a strategy is critical for both agriculture and non-agriculture,
and the revival of small holder cultivation is an essential
aspect of this.
Third, the strategy must emphasise the expansion of
and better delivery systems in the provision of public
services, especially in nutrition, sanitation, health
and education. This allows for improved material and
social conditions and has positive employment effects
directly and through the multiplier process. This in
turn requires increases in public employment, which
incidentally also sets the floors for wages and improves
the bargaining power of workers. This often not recognised
as a crucial element of a possible wage-led strategy,
but it can be extremely significant, and can be used
effectively even in export-oriented economies, as long
as surpluses from industrialisation and exports can
be mobilised to provide wage goods publicly. Indeed,
this has been an important and unrecognised feature
of successful Asian industrialisation from Japan to
the East Asian NICs to (most recently) China. In these
countries, the public provision of affordable and reasonably
good quality housing, transport facilities, basic food,
school education and basic health care all operated
to improve the conditions of life of workers and (indirectly)
therefore to reduce the money wages that individual
employers need to pay workers. This not only reduced
overall labour costs for private employers, but also
provided greater flexibility for producers competing
in external markets, since a significant part of fixed
costs was effectively reduced. It also provided important
multiplier effects that generated employment expansion
in other activities.
Fourth, a related aspect is the need to provide much
better social protection, with more funding, wider coverage
and consolidation, more health spending and more robust
and extensive social insurance programmes including
pensions and unemployment insurance. This is important
in itself, particularly for reducing human insecurity
and gender gaps in living conditions. It also has great
macroeconomic significance because it increases the
presence of countercyclical buffers that reduce the
negative effects of periods of economic downswing.
Obviously, such a strategy requires overall a significant
increase in government spending, which seems to be almost
an unrealistic demand in the current global economic
context. The usual concern is that of finding the resources
for it. In a context in which fiscal deficits are seen
as anathema, increasing public expenditure appears to
be an idealistic and impractical proposal. There are
two reasons why this is not true. The first reason is
that the multiplier effects of public expenditure in
economies with significant unemployment and excess capacity
involve increases in income and therefore also public
revenues, which means that the increases in spending
will not be matched by equivalent increases in deficit.
The second reason (that tax revenues raised from the
rich can pay for this increased spending) is potentially
even more significant in the current socio-political
climate, because it provides an opportunity to redress
the dramatically increasing inequality in assets and
incomes that has come to dominate the global economy.
It is increasingly evident that across the world there
have to be conscious attempts to reduce economic inequalities,
both between countries and within countries. We have
clearly crossed the limits of what is ''acceptable''
inequality in most societies, and future policies will
have to reverse this trend. Paradoxically, the extreme
inequality that is now evident actually makes it potentially
easier to raise resources through taxation, by imposing
reasonable taxes on ''the 1 per cent'' of the population
that is now increasingly the target of the public protests
by ''the 99 per cent''. Far from disrupting economic
activity, as is threatened whenever such taxes are talked
of, the use of such revenues in the directions mentioned
here is more likely to generate more broad-based and
sustainable economic expansion and improved quality
of life overall.
Finally, such increased public spending must also be
associated with some additional critical features. Greater
state involvement must be associated with efforts to
make such involvement more democratic and accountable
to the people, especially those who have been marginalised
or dislocated by the economic growth process. Also,
it is not enough to talk about ''cleaner, greener technologies''
to produce goods that are based on older and increasingly
unviable patterns of consumption. Instead, we need to
think creatively about such consumption itself, and
work out which goods and services are more necessary
and desirable for our societies.
As I mentioned at the start, the ILO is uniquely positioned
to champion and carry forward such an agenda, because
of its tripartite nature and its commitment to the core
values summarized in the concept of decent work. I am
proud to be even a small part of this broad and extremely
significant agenda.
*
Dr. Jayati Ghosh, Professor, Jawaharlal Nehru University
and IDEAs Executive Secretary, is the co-recipient of
the ILO Decent Work Research Prize, 2010. The Prize
was awarded in recognition of her major scholarly contributions
to the analysis of socio-economic relationships and
policy instruments for the advancement of decent work.
This acceptance speech made at the ILO award function
on 11 November, 2011 is available at:
http://www.ilo.org/global/about-the-ilo/press-and-media-centre/videos/events-coverage/WCMS_1677
46/lang--en/index.htm |
|
|
|
|
|
|