It is now almost commonplace to recognize that Indian
agriculture is in a state of crisis. There are numerous
indicators of this crisis: the stagnation of agricultural
GDP and the fall in per capita GDP in agriculture in
recent years; the increased volatility of output and
greater susceptibility of Indian prices to international
price movements; the rising input costs that make it even
more difficult for Indian farmers to compete with the
threat of subsidized imports.
One cited indicator of the problematic condition of Indian
agriculture is the collapse in farm employment generation
in the recent past. While employment in general has been a
major failure of the macroeconomic policies of the past
decade, the decline in agricultural employment generation
has probably been the most startling.
The growth of agricultural employment by usual status
(that is, the number of people reporting themselves as
'usually employed') fell from an annual rate of 2.08 per
cent in the period 1987–88 to 1993–94, to only 0.8 per
cent over 1993–94 to 1999–2000. In terms of daily status,
the fall was even greater, from 2.47 per cent to 0.14 per
cent per year.
Within this, the really sharp fall was in the number of
those classified as 'self-employed' in agriculture, that
is, those working on household-operated holdings. And even
within this category, the most evident decline was in
terms of the number of women reporting themselves as
working on household plots.
What are the reasons for this reduced ability of
cultivation to generate additional work? One explanation
hinges on the expansion of the non-agricultural sector in
rural areas. According to this, labour has been moving out
of agriculture because of greater demand for labour in
other sectors. But this argument is not good enough
because, in fact, the increase in non-agricultural work
has been much less than the decline in agricultural
employment. At least some of this increase in
non-agricultural employment might simply be because rural
residents are desperately searching for any job that can
be had.
Another explanation has to do with technological and
cropping pattern changes that have reduced the demand for
labour in agriculture. There is no doubt that these
factors have been important. Recently, there has been an
increase in mechanization of Indian agriculture which is
labour-saving in nature and so reduces labour demand.
Also, the general thrust of the cropping pattern shifts
(especially towards horticulture and floriculture at the
margin in some areas) may be said to have reduced demand
for labour.
But there is one other factor to be considered-the pattern
of land relations in rural India. It is now clear that
this period witnessed a significant degree of
concentration in terms of operated holdings, which
reflects changes in both ownership and tenancy patterns.
Many small and very marginal peasants have lost their land
and have therefore been forced to search for work as
landless labourers. Surveys also report increased
leasing-in by large farmers from small landowners. There
has been a very large increase in landless households as a
percentage of total rural households at the all-India
level, from around 35 per cent in 1987–88 to as much as 41
per cent in 1999–2000.
It is well known that, for various reasons, those
occupying small holdings tend to intensively use land and
labour to achieve higher per land unit productivity than
larger farms. Typically, this means that they employ more
household members at least in some agricultural work. If
those who previously occupied some land are now
effectively dispossessed and are forced to hire themselves
out as wage labour, they are less likely to get similar
levels of household employment.
In other words, when a particular plot of land is occupied
by small and marginal peasants working on household farms,
it is likely to show higher use of labour than when that
same plot is taken over by a large farmer using hired
labour. Not all of this may be disguised unemployment,
since the fact that small/marginal cultivators also use
other non-land inputs more intensively suggests that they
would use this additional labour to increase per hectare
productivity.
Therefore, increasing landlessness (even in terms of
occupancy holdings) of the rural population may also lead
to less employment generation in agriculture.
The question then remains, why has the proportion of
landless population increased so substantially over these
two periods? This may be because of changes in rural India
that have adversely affected small farmers.
One of the more crucial changes has been the virtual
collapse of formal rural credit, especially for small
cultivators. The reduced availability of credit has very
severe implications especially for small farmers. A number
of input costs have also increased, as fertilizer
subsidies have been reduced, and as water rates and other
user charges have gone up.
In addition, there is some evidence that although real
wage growth slowed down substantially during the 1990s,
real wage rates continued to increase in most parts of the
country. Since the seasonality of agricultural operations
means that most cultivators, whatever the size of holding,
need to hire in some labour during peak seasons, this
raised costs and made hiring out labour more worthwhile
than working on own operated land in peak seasons.
The process of trade liberalization has meant that
domestic agricultural prices have less relation to
domestic demand and supply conditions, and instead follow
world prices. This means that even when the harvest is
lower or there are crop failures, cultivators do not get
any recompense in terms of higher prices.
There is much greater use of a range of monetized inputs,
including new varieties of seed and related inputs
marketed by major multinational companies. Small
cultivators, who have taken on debt (often from informal
credit sources at very high rates of interest) in order to
pay for these cash inputs, then find themselves in real
difficulty if for some reason there is crop failure or
output prices remain low.
All these could be reasons why the proportion of rural
households that is not operating any land at all increased
so much over these periods. This in turn means that there
would be less people reporting themselves as self-employed
in agriculture (which is what is observed) and a general
reduction in employment generation because less people
would be hired than had lost employment from own
cultivation.
It could be argued that there is nothing wrong with
declining employment in agriculture since that after all
is the eventual aim of the development and
industrialization process. By this argument, we should
actually desire negative employment elasticity in
agriculture as workers move out to industry and services,
along the classic pattern observed in the now-developed
countries.
And there, of course, the crux of the problem is that
non-agricultural employment has simply not grown enough to
take up the slack. The fall in employment generation also
has to be seen in the wider context-that is, not of a
dynamic agriculture in a vibrant and growing economy but
of stagnating conditions of cultivation in a rural economy
in which aggregate incomes are also stagnating.
Also, it would be remiss of us to forget that when the
neoliberal reforms were first introduced in the early
1990s, once of the basic claims made was that the policy
package would free cultivators from the straitjacket of
controls and the bias towards urban industry. It was
argued then that the sectors that were seen to reflect the
Indian economy's comparative advantage-that is,
agriculture and labour-intensive manufacturing-would
benefit the most. It was further argued that these sectors
would experience significant increases in employment.
The experience of the past decade has given the lie to all
those claims. The stagnation of agricultural employment,
in this context, points to a very basic flaw in the very
philosophy of the neoliberal reform programme. That could
be one reason why official policy-makers increasingly tend
to downplay the observed realities on Indian farms.
|