Among the
many myths commonly held by the Indian middle class, perhaps the most
prevalent and most tenacious is the idea that it - along with the rich,
of course - pays all the taxes that are received by the Government. So
persistent is this myth that it then forms the basis of further
propositions that this group should be given greater say over the
disposition of tax revenues.
This tendency is exemplified by a prominent national newsmagazine, which
recently ran a cover story declaring that the citizens who paid taxes
were unhappy over the way in which the money was used. Those interviewed
were exclusively from the middle class or richer sections, and in their
replies they assumed the superior role of those who bear the brunt of
government taxation. This in turn meant that they could insist that
democratic functioning required that their opinions be given a far
greater say in the government’s fiscal management. Some of those quoted
even voiced the sentiment that they should be allowed not to pay taxes
as part of their democratic right, since they were dissatisfied with the
quality of government services provided and were willing to provision
these services from private sources instead.
The misconception about incidence of tax burden is not one that is
confined to laypersons with little knowledge of the basics of public
finance. Even in the Economics Departments of major universities, it is
still possible to observe learned theoreticians present abstract
economic models in which an important underlying assumption is that the
poor pay no taxes and are simply recipients of government largesse which
is financed by taxing the rich.
At one level of course, the idea seems intuitively plausible, which is
probably why it is so widespread. After all, taxation is well known to
have a redistributive function, which is actually seen as a valuable
function by many. And surely it is not so unrealistic to suggest that
the richer and middle classes provide the bulk of tax revenue since they
are the ones who pay direct taxes (which are, in turn, proportionate to
income).
There are several problems with this argument, however, and at least
three which are significant. The first is that, despite popular middle
class perception, in fact the Indian economy has one of the lowest rates
of taxation in the world, in terms of aggregate tax as a proportion of
national income. Not only is it already very low in terms of
international comparison, but it has fallen over the 1990s.
The ratio of Central Government tax receipts to GDP was only 11.3 per
cent in 1989-90; by 1999-2000 it had fallen to the miserable proportion
of 8.8 per cent. Even if taxes levied by the State Governments are
included, the total tax-GDP ratio was still only 17 per cent in 1989-90
and fell to 14 per cent by 1999-2000. Compare this to tax-GDP ratios of
more than 40 per cent in most developed countries, and above 30 per cent
in most of Asia. Even in the countries of Sub-Saharan Africa, well known
for their continuing fiscal crisis, tax-GDP ratios are typically in
excess of those in India.
Not only that, but in fact the bulk of tax revenue in India comes in the
form of indirect taxes. Indirect taxes were on average more than 70 per
of Central Government tax revenues through the 1990s, and in fact would
have been even more but for the decline in customs duties related to
import liberalisation over this period.
For
the state governments, indirect taxes amount to more than 95 per cent of
their total tax collection. Thus, if both State and Central taxes are
taken into account, indirect taxes amounted to 82 per cent of total
taxes and direct taxes accounted for only 18 per cent.
So
it turns out that the dominant part of tax revenues comes from indirect
taxes, which are accepted to be broadly regressive and affect
lower-income groups disproportionately. It is sometimes argued that the
rich - or the upper-income groups - pay the bulk of the indirect taxes
as well, because they spend more on consuming items (by definition,
almost). This is not just debatable but in all probability wrong, but of
course a refutation would require detailed analysis of the
commodity-wise tax incidence and a consideration of the spending
patterns of households according to size classes of expenditure, which
cannot be attempted here.
Nevertheless, the pertinent point is that, since by far the major part
of taxes are in the from of indirect taxes which are known to be
regressive, it is likely that a disproportionate part of the tax burden
actually falls on the poorer households. In other words, it is likely
that poorer people actually pay out a larger share of their income in
the form of taxes, than the rich. This complete reversal of the common
middle class notion is the one which is likely to be closer to the
truth.
Of course, even the pattern of indirect taxation itself can have
particular distributive implications, and can vary depending upon the
choices made by the fiscal authority. To take an example, in the latest
Central Government Budget, there was a “rationalisation” of excise duty
rates which was widely applauded in the financial press and by middle
class commentators. This measure merged the three rates of 8, 16 and 24
per cent into one common rate of 16 per cent for all items (barring a
very select few).
This sounds quite harmless and even desirable at one level; but what did
it imply in distributive terms ? Luxury commodities such as cars, air
conditioners, durable consumption goods and so on saw the rate of duty
fall from 24 per cent to 16 per cent. By contrast, a whole range of
items of mass consumption, ranging from soaps and local detergents of
common use to certain food items, saw the rate of duty double from 8 to
16 per cent.
This is of course quite a stark example of how even indirect taxes can
become an instrument for transferring income from the poor to the rich,
quite apart from the fact that they are fundamentally regressive anyway.
But it is very much a part and parcel of general fiscal management over
the past decade, where the burden of taxation has been borne by a large
mass of population that then receives very little benefit in terms of
the direction of state expenditure.
Despite, this, the myth persists, and the upper income groups continue
to see themselves as those bearing the tax burden for the rest of the
economy. In a sense, the unwillingness of these groups to pay taxes -
which is largely responsible for the low tax-GDP ratios in the Indian
economy even at existing tax rates - reflects a more basic problem with
our elites. This is the growing tendency to extract as much as possible
from the system, while resisting any attempts to put something back in.
Only when this tendency is firmly resisted, and basic discipline in
terms of respecting the rule of law in taxation is enforced, would we
have anything approaching the minimal requirements even for an efficient
capitalist system, which is otherwise what our middle classes seem so
keen to espouse.