It used to be said of
the Bourbon kings of France that they "learn nothing
and forget nothing". The same can be said of the
current Indian Establishment. Lakhs of people have
been demonstrating across the globe against the
policies of "globalization" which have wrought havoc
on the lives of the people in the third world. Lakhs
of people demonstrated on the 26th of
February in Delhi itself at the call of the Central
Trade Unions against these policies. Financial crises
in the wake of these policies have hit a whole range
of countries from East Asia to Latin America. Over
large tracts of the third world, governments pursuing
such policies have been replaced through the exercise
of popular franchise by regimes committed to fighting
"globalization". But our Establishment proceeds as if
nothing has changed. The same old cliches are trotted
out, the same borrowed theories from Washington DC are
peddled, and the same double-speak learnt from the
metropolis is resorted to, even as the same policies
are pursued relentlessly. An example of this Bourbon
attitude is the Budget presented by Jaswant Singh on
February 28, which carries forward the "neo-liberal
agenda", to the accompaniment of cheers from the
Confederation of Indian Industry.
Lest I be accused of unfairness, just consider the
following. The two obvious problems facing the economy
at this moment are: the desperate condition of the
peasantry owing to the output price-crash which has
been imported from the world market under the WTO-dictated
"liberal trade" regime, and the dwindling employment
opportunities in every sector, including, in
particular, agriculture, which underlie acute and
persistent poverty, and to which even the government's
own Economic Survey this year has drawn
attention. What does the Budget offer on each score?
The Finance Minister has chosen this very time to hit
the peasantry. Fertilizer prices have been jacked up.
Light diesel oil, used for running pump-sets, would
now attract an additional excise duty of Rs.1.50 per
litre; and this is in addition to the general hike in
petrol and diesel prices: the 50 paise per litre cess
on diesel and the Rs.50 per tonne duty on domestic and
imported crude oil (the latter in the name of the
National Calamity Contingency Fund). In short,
precisely when the output prices are low, the input
prices have been jacked up, catching the peasantry in
a double-squeeze.
To be sure, a Price Stabilization Fund of Rs.500
crores has been set up for tea, coffee and rubber; and
agriculture is now supposed to pay an interest rate on
credit that is no more than 2 percentage points above
the Prime Lending Rate. But the former measure would
typically benefit the plantation sector, not so much
the peasantry. And since the amount of credit
to agriculture has been dwindling in relative terms in
recent years, with private, especially foreign, banks
falling way below the stipulated "norm" (and even
nationalized banks violating them), a reduction in the
lending rate can scarcely bring much
comfort. What is striking about all this, and
illustrates the double-speak mentioned above, is the
fact that the Finance Minister has included
agriculture as one of his "five priority areas" even
while imposing the squeeze on the peasantry!
As regards employment, the Finance Minister had an
excellent opportunity to launch a large-scale
Employment Generation Programme. Owing to the
deflationary squeeze on purchasing power in rural
India, there are plenty of foodgrains stocks available
with the government at present, notwithstanding last
year's drought and the secular slowdown in foodgrain
output growth in the nineties. Industry too has
substantial unutilized capacity to meet the demand for
the non-food component of any Employment Programme.
Banks are flush with liquidity which they would be
more than willing to lend to the government. And if
the government does launch such a programme, since the
bulk of the demand would accrue back to the government
sector itself, the net indebtedness of the
government would increase only fractionally.
The Finance Minister however has not used this
opportunity. All he has done instead is to spend
Rs.507 crores more on the Antyodaya scheme, and
this he claims to be a major attack on poverty (garib
ke pet me dana)! The Antyodaya Anna Yojana is an
even more narrowly-targeted programme within the
already narrow Targeted Public Distribution Scheme,
whereby food is made available to a small subset of
the Below-Poverty-Line population at the subsidized
rate of Rs.2 per kg. of wheat and Rs.3 per kg. of
rice. Since the TPDS itself, which catered to the BPL
population as a whole, was riven with problems
of under-numeration and misidentification of BPL
households, and became one contributory factor towards
the reduction of off-take from the PDS, the further
targeting within the TPDS would be even more
fruitless. Indeed the High Level Committee on
Long-term Grain Policy had recommended a complete
abandonment of TPDS in favour of a comprehensive and
uniform PDS. (Under such a scheme the BPL population
can always be provided adequate purchasing power
through Employment Programmes). The Minister has
instead gone in for further targeting through the
Antyodaya Scheme, which, as the High-level Committee
had warned, would only increase the budgetary drain
without significantly improving foodgrain off-take
(and hence ipso facto making much impact on
poverty).
In short, the problem of rural unemployment is not
addressed at all. At the same time, a host of measures
have been devised, such as the de-reservation of items
hitherto reserved for the Small-Scale sector, and the
reduction in import duties (the peak Customs Duty has
been brought down from 30 to 25 percent), which would
hurt urban employment through their adverse impact on
small industries.
But then what of the claim that the Budget is a
"growth-oriented" one? Such a claim which by now has
become routine for every budget is particularly hollow
in the context of the present one, since it does
not provide for any increase in budget support for
plan outlay in real terms. Budget support for
Central Plan is supposed to increase in nominal terms
by 5.8 percent over the current year's revised
estimate; total Central assistance for State and Union
Territory Plans is supposed to increase by 6.4
percent. These figures are not too different from the
underlying inflation rate assumed in the budget
itself. (The current inflation rate (WPI) is 4.4
percent, and the Finance Minister acknowledges that
the budget would contribute towards an increase in
it). The proposed increase in the Central Plan outlay
itself is only 8 percent in nominal terms, which
scarcely entails any real increase. Indeed even if we
take all expenditures, plan and non-plan,
capital and revenue, transfers (including interest
payments) and others, we still find a nominal increase
of only 8.6 percent, which means no more than a couple
of percentage points of increase in real terms. This
in short is a highly deflationary budget, which far
from promoting growth, would only contribute towards a
perpetuation and accentuation of the prevailing demand
constraint. The fact that this budget is being
criticized on precisely the opposite grounds, for
having "too large a fiscal deficit", even in the midst
of a recession, shows only the utter poverty of
thought that currently prevails.
This is not to say that the budget would not lead to
an acceleration in inflation. It certainly would, but
that is because of the cost-push it has imparted to
the economy, via the withdrawal of subsidies on inputs
like fertilizers, via hikes in petrol and diesel
prices, and via the increase in the excise duties on a
whole range of commodities which earlier had attracted
less than 8 percent excise duty but would now be
subject to this minimum rate. Expenditure and
income deflation in other words is perfectly
compatible with price inflation caused by a
cost-push, which after all is why unemployment and
inflation can, and do, co-exist, and occasionally even
grow in tandem. The budget is pushing the economy
towards such a predicament.
The deflationary nature of the budget is sought to be
camouflaged by grandiose announcements about
infrastructure development and health insurance. But,
the contribution of this year's budget towards the
Rs.60,000 crore infrastructure development plan
happens to be a paltry Rs. 2,000 crores. Not only
does the figure 60,000 refer to the entire cost of the
projects spread over a number of years, but it is
optimistically assumed to be financed from diverse
sources, among which the public exchequer happens to
be one tiny contributor. Likewise the Health Insurance
Scheme does not refer to any comprehensive plan to
spread public health facilities all over the country.
It means in fact just the opposite: the people have to
take recourse to private, and hence expensive, health
facilities, whose availability in remote areas cannot
even be ensured by the government. They would get back
a part of the expenses involved in hospitalization
cases, but only if they have been regularly paying
insurance premia. The scheme in other words
camouflages an actual disengagement of the government
from the health sector.
The claim that the budget is "growth-oriented" is
based however on invoking a myth, namely that doling
out concessions to the capitalists (including foreign
ones) ipso facto promotes growth. This
self-serving proposition which capitalists always put
forward and which has now become officially
respectable is utterly vacuous, both theoretically and
empirically. Capitalists invest only when demand is
sufficiently buoyant; when this is not the case, no
matter how large a transfer is made to them from the
public exchequer, they would not invest. They would
simply pocket the transfers, which is why this
self-serving argument is put forward with particular
vehemence precisely in periods of recession when
profits are otherwise low. Our own experience bears
this out. For several years now, every successive
budget has given concessions to the private corporate
sector for stimulating investment and output growth;
and yet gross capital formation in the private
corporate sector as a proportion of GDP has stagnated
and, of late, even come down.
Deflation is the inevitable fate of any economy that
gets trapped in the vortex of international
speculative financial flows. For the promotion of
growth therefore it is necessary that the economy gets
out of this trap, by arresting and reversing the
process of so-called "financial liberalization" (which
is the mechanism through which economies get trapped).
The Budget however does the very opposite: it allows
foreign direct investment up to 74 percent in Indian
private banks, an increase from the current 49
percent, even as it removes all restriction on voting
rights in banking companies. At the same time it
allows the "merger" of private banking companies with
nationalized banks. By these measures, it opens the
way for the takeover by foreigners of Indian banks,
and the takeover by the private sector, whether Indian
or foreign, of nationalized banks, i.e. for both the
de-Indianization of private banks and the
privatization of nationalized banks. These measures
clearly carry the neo-liberal agenda forward; the
deflationary nature of the budget is a symptom of
this.
A notable feature of the budget is the proposed
debt-swap vis a vis the states. With the decline in
nominal interest rates this had become a long overdue
measure, and the states had been demanding this for
some time. Whatever succour to state finances this
measure would bring (the figure Rs.81,000 crores
mentioned by the Finance Minister is somewhat
misleading, since it refers to the total savings by
states over the entire residual maturity period of the
loans and includes savings on account of both interest
payments and deferred loan payments), would be offset,
partly at any rate, by the shift to VAT from sales
tax. That there would be a loss to the states from
this shift is now admitted by the Finance Minister
himself; what is unclear is why the Central
government, which has been pressing for this shift,
would be compensating the states for the revenue loss
only in the first year (the compensation tapers off to
75 percent in the second and 50 percent in the third
year, after which presumably there is no further
compensation). It is intriguing why the state
governments, which are collectively experiencing an
even more acute fiscal crisis than the Centre, have
allowed themselves to be cajoled into accepting this
revenue loss, which, in some cases at least would be
quite substantial, given the overwhelming importance
of the sales tax in state government revenues.
This budget throws into sharp relief the changes
occurring in the class character of the State in the
era of globalization. Analysts of political economy
during the dirigiste period used to identify
the urban bourgeoisie, the landlords (whether in their
pristine feudal garb or donning the capitalist
mantle), and the emerging class of rural capitalists
as constituting the ruling class combine behind State
power. In the era of globalization however, changes
occur both in the composition of the ruling class
combine and in the relative weights of the different
elements within it. In particular as the economy is
opened up to the unfettered movement of finance
capital, the relative weight of the rural component of
the ruling combine declines, even as a new "globalized"
component of the bourgeoisie, consisting of financial
operators, speculators, local frontmen for MNCs,
multinational banks and foreign agencies, NRI
capitalists, together with certain segments of the
earlier bourgeoisie, acquire greater importance. The
fact that a government which pleads incapacity to
maintain the fertilizer subsidy, has no compunctions
at the same time about "disinvesting" valuable public
property "for a song" is a symptom of this shift.