It is only when all of this
failed that the recent decision to slash the APL issue price by 30 per
cent was taken. Implicit in that decision are two perceptions that have
been driven home by sheer experience. The first is that upward adjustments
in the issue price with the aim of curtailing subsidies is
counterproductive, inasmuch as it results in a fall in offtake and an
increase in the costs incurred on carrying stocks. The second is that
targeting is a failure inasmuch as it ensures that offtake does not keep
pace with autonomous procurement, and results in embarrassingly large
stocks and unplanned subsidy levels. These perceptions imply that the
government's statement that the cut in the APL issue price is purely
temporary and is aimed at clearing stocks is pure bravado. The only
circumstances where it can economically sustain high issue prices would be
one in which foodgrain production and procurement fall substantially. But
that would be a situation when high issue prices may not be politically
feasible.
Moreover, if production and
procurement do not fall, as is unlikely in the coming season given the
munificence of the monsoon, then even the cut in APL prices may not be
enough to reduce the stock held by the government. The willingness of
farmers to sell to the government at the procurement price depends in the
final analysis on the price prevailing in the open market. That price
depends in turn on open market demand, which consists of demand from two
sources: those who are not permitted to access the PDS or choose not to
use the access they have; and those who cannot access the PDS because of
its inadequate spread.
If the cut in APL prices is
to achieve its objective, demand from the first of these sources (that is
those with access to the distribution system) should increase. If this
does indeed occur, the open market demand for food would correspondingly
fall at a time when the harvest is expected to be good. Farmers would
therefore be all the more keen to hand over their stocks to the government
at the procurement price. Thus, a part of the reduction in stocks with the
government resulting from higher offtake would be neutralised by higher
levels of procurement.
The implications of this
should be clear. The only ways in which the limited objective of reducing
stocks can be achieved are by dismantling the procurement system or by
substantially increasing the total demand for foodgrain (rather than
changing the distribution of a given demand across the PDS and the open
market, as APL price adjustments predominantly achieve). There have been
sinister moves in recent times to do away with the procurement system,
which is considered unsustainable within a purely marketist ‘policy'
framework. There is reason to believe that the proposal to decentralise
procurement to the States, backed by “financial assistance” from the
Centre, is one form those moves are taking.
Advocated on the grounds of
efficiency, that proposal has as its primary objective the reduction of
central involvement in food procurement. And once decentralisation occurs,
procurement by financially-constrained State Governments would
substantially depend on the extent of central financial support. The
Centre would, however, find it politically far easier to curtail such
financial support to the States than to curtail procurement under the
present system. Once the States take on the responsibility of procurement,
they would find it difficult to explain low procurement as being the
result of the Centre's manipulation rather than their own decisions. The
Centre would have in essence dismantled the procurement system, but a
large part of the responsibility for the same would have to be carried by
the State governments. We should not forget that the last government in Kerala had to carry a substantial part of the responsibility for falling
prices of primary products such as coconut and rubber, resulting from the
Centre's liberalisation agenda.
Thus, the only acceptable
option to deal with the excess-stock situation is to substantially
increase the total domestic demand for food. There is no better way of
doing this than by linking food demand with wage payments in a new and
substantially large centrally sponsored food-for-work programme aimed at
creating rural infrastructure. It is no doubt true that this would involve
associated rupee expenditures, which provides the base for arguments that
given the already high level of the fiscal deficit the government,
launching such a food-for-work thrust is not feasible. There are two
arguments against such a position. First, the argument that the fiscal
deficit is India's principal economic problem is by no means valid in a
situation where there are no supply-side constraints. After all food
stocks are at historically high levels, foreign exchange reserves are at
comfortable levels and Indian industry is burdened with large excess
capacities. In such a situation, the provision of a fiscal stimulus to
raise output growth and reduce employment and poverty is eminently
reasonable. And when the deficit-financed expenditures are required only
to finance part of the expenditure, the case for such expenditures are
stronger.
Consider the following
back-of-the-envelope calculation. The wage cost of a rural works programme
is likely to amount to about 60 per cent of the total cost of the project,
and about 60 per cent of that wage bill can be met with payments in kind
(food). This would make the food component in project costs about 36 per
cent of the total. If the government chooses to use 20 million tonnes of
its stocks over a three-year period to finance such a scheme, the food
component of the projects commissioned would amount to around Rs. 10,000
crore, since the average BPL value of foodgrain is about Rs. 5000 a tonne.
This would imply that the total cost of the programme would be about
28,000 crore over three years or around Rs. 9000 crore a year. Assuming
that the average multiplier of around 4 prevailing in the economy as a
whole holds in the case of such rural works as well, the scheme would
immediately generate additional output of around Rs. 36,000 crore every
year for three years. Further, if the projects are properly planned and
the average capital output ratio of 4 holds, the scheme would generate a
permanent increase in output of around Rs. 7,000 crore every year after
those three years. Thus, incomes and employment would increase, and food
demand would be directly and indirectly stimulated, putting to good use
food stocks that would otherwise rot in FCI godowns.
All this assumes
significance because the Finance Minister himself has argued that some
fiscal stimulus is needed just now to stall the downturn in the economy.
In fact, he has directed financial advisors in all ministries to step up
capital expenditures. In addition, PSUs are to be tapped to obtain
additional dividends and interest payments, so that the non-tax revenues
of the government can be beefed-up and overall expenditures expanded.
These initiatives are likely to be far less effective than the option of a
food-for-work programme of the kind advocated above. They are also likely
to be far less effective in resolving a problem other than growth
confronting the government, namely, that of an embarrassingly high level
of food stock that at present has no takers.