The
Competition Bill, which would alter substantially
the nature and thrust of anti-trust intervention by
the government, is among the 43 bills which passed
through parliament in the winter session that ended
recently. With its passage, the Monopolies and Restrictive
Trade Practices (MRTP) Act that governed the Indian
government’s anti-trust agenda is to be scrapped and
the MRTP Commission is to be replaced by a Competition
Commission of India.
This event marks the completion of a process in which
the earlier practice of limiting the size and spread
of groups involving related or interconnected units
has been given up in favour of ensuring that it is
not so much size that is the issue as the adoption
of practices that limit or reduce the extent of competition.
This transition had begun much earlier when the government
had done away with the definition of a dominant group
or undertaking based on asset size, allowing the erstwhile
‘monopolistic’ groups to freely invest in new areas
or expand in existing areas, subject to the industry-wise
regulations that were in vogue. Inasmuch as these
industry-wise regulations were being relaxed in any
case, the process of “liberating” Indian monopoly
from the constraints set by state policy in the past
had begun. The recently passed competition bill formalises
this process as well as sets out the redefined framework
for anti-trust intervention.
By adopting the legislation the government of India
has implicitly accepted a number of arguments on the
nature and role of monopoly. The most crucial is that
the market dominance resulting from size may not in
itself be inimical from the point of view of competition.
This position could possibly be justified on three
grounds. First, it could be based on the view that
while concentration and oligopoly could spell the
end of “free competition” it need not negate competition
altogether. In fact, competition between large firms
could be even more intense, resulting in more rapid
innovation as well as price competition, both of which
benefit consumers. Second, it could be argued that
given the capital-intensive nature of new technologies
in many areas, innovation may require firms to be
large both in terms of capital investment and in terms
of output relative to domestic market size. Third,
it could be argued that the size and domestic market
share of large incumbents need not matter, so long
as there are no significant barriers to entry of new
firms and there are no barriers to competition from
imports from abroad.
In fact, it is the last of these, i.e., competition
from abroad, which provides the anchor for the argument
that the size of a firm relative to other domestic
producers or relative to the size of the domestic
market need not matter. There are, however, a number
of features of the international and domestic marketplace
that this argument ignores. To start with, not all
goods and services are tradables, and competition
from abroad cannot serve as a check on monopolistic
and restrictive trade practices in the case of goods
and services that are not traded or only traded to
a small extent. Further, the presence of more than
one large firm in a particular market is no guarantee
of intense oligopolistic competition, so long as the
potential for collusion and the sharing of surpluses
garnered at the expense of the consumer exist. Finally,
in areas or segments where the international market
itself is dominated by one or a few producers, as
for example is true in the case of drugs and pharmaceuticals,
the domestic producer/s can be the same as those which
are the dominant players in the international market.
Thus, imports from the same firm or from parent firms
of subsidiaries cannot be a check on the misuse of
market dominance. Inasmuch as the Bill does not distinguish
between “domestic” and “foreign” monopolies, the check
exerted by international competition on domestic monopoly
is substantially diluted. It is only by making such
a distinction and making the case that there is need
for developing countries to build their own large
firms by international standards that the decision
to remove restrictions on the growth of large “domestic”
firms can be justified. That is, the advocacy of unrestricted
size for domestic firms must be couched in a framework
wherein the effort is to protect domestic firms from
international competition so as to nurture internationally
competitive domestic monopolies.
Once this argument is made, a further round of intervention
becomes inevitable, especially in areas where one
or few firms control a large share of a market in
which they are being nurtured through protection.
Such protection can be used to earn superprofits at
the expense of the consumer. This could discourage
production for the international market, since the
domestic market is far more lucrative. And, the lack
of competition from imports and lack of desire to
export could result in a situation where innovation
is neglected. Consumers and the system would be the
losers. Thus, intervention to discipline domestic
capital either by fiat or by encouraging competition
between domestic producers, especially in areas where
one or a few producers control a substantial share
of the market becomes inevitable.
Thus even if the size of domestic firms is not to
be restricted, that policy should not necessarily
apply to large international firms, whose presence
in the domestic market must be regulated. Further,
intervention aimed at preventing domestic firms from
exploiting their monopolistic position in a fashion
that would adversely affect consumer choice and prices
and constrain the pace of innovation needs to be formulated.
Unfortunately, the competition bill, which treats
size as being immaterial avoids all these decisions.
The government itself argues that the bill seeks to
(i) counter anti-competitive practices such as cartelisation,
collusive bidding and bid-rigging; (ii) check abuse
of market dominance; and (iii) lay down the procedures
with regard to mergers and acquisitions (M&A).
To this end the bill seeks to set up a Competition
Commission of India, with adjudicatory powers and
the power to impose penalties.
The point to note is that the intent of the bill is
not to deal with dominance per se, but the abuse of
dominance. It enjoins the CCI to promote competition
as well as impose penalties on those who are judged
to have reduced competition in any market by (a) directly
or indirectly determining purchase or sale prices;
(b) limiting or controlling production, supply, markets,
technical development, investment or provision of
services; (c) sharing the market or source of production
or provision of services by way of allocation of geographical
area of market, or type of goods or services, or number
of customers in the market; or (d) directly or indirectly
indulging in bid rigging or collusive bidding, It
considers any agreement (formal or informal) amongst
enterprises or persons with regard to production,
supply, distribution, storage, sale or pricing of,
or trade in goods or provision of services, which
involve (a) a tie-in arrangement; (b) an exclusive
supply agreement; (c) an exclusive distribution agreement;
(d) a refusal to deal; or (e) the maintenance of resale
prices, to be anti-competitive in nature.
Thus the intent of the bill is not to deal with the
structures that lead to anti-competitive practices,
but to deal with such practices on a case by case
basis so as to protect the consumer, defined as any
purchaser of a good or service. Either on its own
or on receipt of a complaint or reference from any
individual, agency or the government, the Commission
and its various offices can launch an investigation,
arrive at a judgement and impose certain penalties.
Given the fact that the structures that lead to anti-competitive
practices are to be left untouched, it can be expected
that the number of cases where anti-competitive activity
is likely to occur would be large. How and when the
Commission would have the time to deal with all of
these or even the more significant ones among them
is unclear. There is a strong likelihood that delays
would ensure that whatever little anti-trust element
remains under the new dispensation would be substantially
diluted.
The only instance where the structures that lead to
anticompetitive behaviour are sought to be engaged
is in the effort to regulate mergers and acquisitions.
Even here the threshold limit for mergers and/or acquisitions
that are to be monitored by the CCI from the point
of view of their impact on competition is set at Rs.
1000 crore in terms of the aggregate assets of the
combining entities or Rs. 3000 crore in terms of aggregate
sales. We must note that it is asset size alone, and
not size together with market share, which is taken
to define the threshold for monitoring. That is the
potential for abuse of market strength is rather loosely
defined. Even in the case of such mergers, the bill
leaves it to the entities concerned to report the
merger for consideration by the Commission. Such voluntary
reporting is expected to occur if the merging entities
want to ensure that their merger does not adversely
affect the competitive environment. Since, even now,
all mergers and acquisitions have to be reported to
the courts and are governed by guidelines issued by
the Securities and Exchange Board of India, it is
unlikely that firms would voluntarily turn to the
CCI for one more scrutiny. This despite the fact that
the Bill specifies that the CCI should complete its
task within 90 days, which should fall within the
six month timeframe provided to the courts.
Thus, both in terms of the ability to deal with actual
anti-competitive behaviour and in terms of its ability
to prevent such behaviour by engaging the structures
that lead in that direction, the Bill is clearly inadequate.
It is likely, therefore, that the Bill would do little
to deal with the anti-competitive tendencies that
are being unleashed in a liberalised environment in
which large firms, including large transnational firms,
have the freedom to expand existing capacities, create
new capacities and acquire capacities created by other
producers, domestic or foreign.