The message from the WTO mini-ministerial at Tokyo
(14–16 February) is clear. There are no takers for
free trade in the international system. In the second
of the series of 'informal' mini-ministerial meetings
being convened to forge an as-yet elusive consensus on
the framework for the Doha Round of world trade talks,
the twenty-two participating countries (out of
twenty-five who were invited) could not agree on any
issue of significance.
The challenge for the Doha Round, we must recall, lies
in the new issues that have been taken on board,
including the four Singapore issues—namely,
investment, competition policy, transparency in public
procurement and trade facilitation. But even before
discussion on these could begin, the 'select' invitees
were bogged down by the problem of clinching a deal on
older issues, principally agriculture and
trade-related intellectual property rights (TRIPs).
The principal stumbling block is agriculture. Stuart
Harbinson, Chairman of WTO's agricultural negotiations
working group set up to draft the 'modalities',
including numerical targets and formulae, by which
countries can frame their liberalization commitments,
released his draft report well ahead of the 31 March
deadline and just prior to the Tokyo meet. The report
indeed makes far-reaching recommendations.
On agricultural tariffs, it separates commodities into
three categories: those with ad valorem tariffs
greater than 90 per cent, between 15 and 90 per cent
and below 15 per cent. In the case of the developed
countries, the report proposes that the simple average
tariff reduction rate for these groups should be 60,
50 and 40 per cent respectively, and the minimum
reduction per tariff line 45, 35 and 25 per cent.
Thus, the higher the currently prevailing tariff, the
greater will be the proportionate reduction
commitment.
The report also proposes that domestic support in the
form of Blue Box payments or direct payments under
production-limiting programmes, liberally resorted to
by the European Union, be reduced by 50 per cent over
five years. Further, aggregate support, including
input and price subsidies, are to be reduced by 60 per
cent over a similar period, and export subsidies are
to be completely phased out through a two-step
process: those accounting for 50 per cent of budgetary
outlays are to go at the end of six years and the rest
at the end of nine years.
What the Harbinson report does not do is propose a
reduction of Green Box payments, or fixed payments
made to farmers independent of their production
levels, which were defined during the Uruguay Round
process as being non-trade-distorting. This has been a
demand of some developing countries and critics of the
Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture. In practice,
these payments too affect the level of production and,
therefore, the volume of world supplies and world
prices. By ignoring these payments, the draft report
does not fundamentally go against government
protection for farmers in developed countries at the
expense of 'freer' world trade. What it does do is to
make a case for adopting the US route of migrating
from conventional subsidies to Green Box payments in
all countries, including those in the EU.
The problem here is that migration from conventional
support, including Blue Box payments, to Green Box
payments, is far easier in land-abundant countries or
land-surplus countries, like the US and parts of Latin
America, than in land short countries, like the EU
nations and Japan. In land-abundant countries,
implicit or explicit rents are lower and farmers do
not have to extend cultivation to far less fertile
tracts to maintain a reasonable level of production.
Since costs would rise as less fertile land is broken
into, such production levels also tend to be justified
by unsubsidized market prices of inputs and outputs.
As a result, a given Green Box-style fixed payment can
go a long way in sustaining farm incomes. And the US
does provide huge direct support payments, especially
to large farms.
In land-short countries, however, explicit or implicit
rents are much higher and costs of cultivation rise
much faster as farmers extend cultivation into less
fertile, marginal lands. If, in such a situation,
subsidies and Blue Box payments are withdrawn and
substituted with a fixed direct income payment, the
effect on production is likely to be much larger,
resulting in employment and income losses for farmers
and substantially increased penetration of imported
agricultural commodities. It is probably this factor
which constrains the process of migration to Green Box
payments in the EU and Japan. Also, in addition to
forcing the pace of such migration, if export
subsidies are to be done away with, farmers from
land-short countries, especially the EU nations, will
be deprived of any access to the large market for
agricultural exports, increasing their income losses.
Not surprisingly, responses to the Harbinson proposals
have differed widely even within the developed country
camp. The US Trade Representative's office was quick
to welcome the draft report, expressing its
appreciation of the call for elimination of export
subsidies and going on to say that deeper cuts were
needed in tariffs and trade-distorting domestic
subsidies that would narrow the wide disparities
between WTO members.
Japan's Agriculture Minister, Tadamori Oshima, on the
other hand, declared that the draft was 'too
ambitious', and that the proposed import tariff
reductions were 'not acceptable'. In his view: 'If
this plan is implemented it would be devastating to
Japanese farming.' Franz Fischler, the EU Agriculture
Commissioner, argued that the draft favoured exporting
countries and distributed the pain unequally. Pushing
the point that the draft favoured the US as compared
with other countries, he denounced the proposals as
'unbalanced', since it unfairly sought to crack down
on export subsidies while being much more lenient on
other forms of farm support. He was also not too happy
about the draft's effort to extend special and
differential treatment to developing countries. While
conceding that industrialized countries had to 'give
more chances' to agricultural imports from developing
countries, he went on to say: 'If you look at the
paper, everything will be required of us and nothing
of the others.'
The fact of the matter is that the Harbinson
draftreport, while recognizing the special problems of
developing countries, leaves untouched their demands
for (i) the reduction and elimination of Green Box
support, which they are financially in no position to
match; (ii) freedom to impose countervailing import
duties to match the huge subsidies provided by the
OECD countries to their farmers and reduce imports;
(iii) greater freedom to protect domestic production
of strategic crops that are crucial to food security
and the livelihoods of poor farmers; and (iv) more
viable special and differential treatment measures.
Developing countries need to ensure greater unity to
make sure that, if and when a deal is struck on
agricultural issues, their requirements are addressed
more fully than has been done in the Harbinson text.
But their problems do not end there. They will have a
much more difficult time when it comes to other areas,
including industrial tariffs, TRIPs and the new
'Singapore issues'. This was clear from the fact that
the US, which was presenting itself as the champion of
free trade in agriculture (even while exploiting to
the full the potential of Green Box payments), refused
to give in on the crucial issue of developing country
access to cheaper, life-saving patented medicines when
confronted with medical emergencies.
At Doha it was recognized that WTO provisions on
intellectual property needed to be amended and that
poor countries should be allowed to access cheaper
generic versions of expensive patented medicines in
order to deal with public health emergencies resulting
from epidemics such as HIV-AIDS, tuberculosis and
malaria. To that end, countries were to be provided
the right to resort to compulsory licensing of the
drugs concerned. But ambiguity remained on the
question of defining a medical emergency and on
whether a poor country without adequate manufacturing
capability can obtain a compulsory licence to have the
drug produced in and imported from another country
with the appropriate manufacturing capacity.
A final decision on these matters was to be arrived at
by December 2002, a deadline, which was missed because
the US government succumbed to pressures from its
domestic pharmaceutical industry, which claims that
the provision could be misused and lead to 'drug
piracy'. Critics have long argued that the case for
patent protection on the grounds of encouraging
investment in research and development and ensuring
technical progress has been overstated. To start with,
R&D investment is one among many forms of sunk costs
that an entrepreneur taking a risk to make a profit
has to undertake. If a poor farmer incurring the sunk
cost of investing in land development is not to be
protected but forced to compete in a liberal trade
environment where prices are volatile, the case to
protect R&D investments by large multinationals, which
can spend large amounts on marketing and distribution,
from 'imitative' competition, is that much weaker. If,
in addition, such protection is to be granted for
fifteen to twenty years, despite the fact that rapid
technical change has reduced the economic life of most
product innovations, it can hardly be justified within
the framework of free trade that the WTO espouses.
However, having won concessions for its pharmaceutical
industry, which is as mollycoddled as the US farmer,
the US government is not willing to step back even in
the humanitarian circumstances that a medical
emergency involves. As a concession to the US, Perez
Motta, Mexico's WTO envoy and chairman of the
medicines talks, has proposed a compromise which
avoids designating specific diseases and instead
limits the compulsory licensing 'concession' to
'national emergencies or other circumstances of
extreme urgency'. But this not good enough for the US,
which has also not welcomed a proposal made by Brazil
at Tokyo on the manufacturing capacity issue. The
proposal suggests that the World Health Organization
should be designated as the agency which will decide
whether poor countries have adequate capacity to
manufacture life-saving generic drugs themselves when
confronted with public health crises. Only if they are
found lacking in such capacity will they be permitted
to import cheaper versions of imitation drugs from
more advanced developing countries with pharmaceutical
sectors, such as Brazil, India or Thailand.
The EU, with its own contingent of large
pharmaceutical producers, has welcomed the Brazilian
proposal as a step forward in bridging the 'confidence
gap', but the US has chosen to ignore it for the time
being. In sum, there is no agreement among the rich
countries on freeing trade, on relaxing irrational
patent protection mandated by the Uruguay Round, or on
accommodating the special needs of the developing
countries. In an effort to give the Tokyo meet some
substance, ministers expressed satisfaction that the
Harbinson draft report is serving as a 'catalyst' for
debate.
This is not to say that the Tokyo meeting is without
significance. Like its predecessor at Sydney, the
Tokyo mini-ministerial has made it clear that there is
little democracy in the process through which the
shape of the international system is forged. Tokyo was
another example of 'informal meetings' that have
become the staple of international trade negotiations
since the Uruguay Round. During that Round,
'consensus' was built by first getting a selected set
of relatively 'influential' members to agree on a
minimum
agenda.
Having achieved at that consensus, the other WTO
members, especially the smaller countries from Africa,
Asia and Latin America, were forced to accept that
programme
at the infamous 'green room meetings', in which
negotiators deprived of their aides were huddled
together in long drawn-out sessions and tired into
submission. Twenty-five selected countries out of a
total of 145 WTO members were invited to Tokyo, of
which twenty-two attended. There is to be a similar
meeting at New Delhi in March. And in all probability,
as the 'Doha process' rolls on, there will be even
smaller meetings, including special summits between US
and EU negotiators, such as the one at which the Blair
House accord on Blue Box measures and the Peace Clause
was worked out during the Uruguay Round. The real
losers in that game will be the poorest developing
countries.
It is not just that there are no takers for free trade
among those claiming to be working towards
institutionalizing a freer trade regime. There is
little hope of a fair deal for the
developing countries either.