|
|
|
|
Budget 2004-05: The (Modified) Turnover
Tax |
|
Aug
02nd 2004, Parthapratim Pal |
|
The
Securities Transaction Tax (STT) or the turnover tax
introduced in the Union Budget for 2004-05 has been
a controversial move. As an immediate impact of the
announcement of the STT, there was more than a hundred
point drop of the Bombay Stock Exchange sensitivity
index (Sensex). Though the Sensex partially recovered
subsequently, the threat of imposition of the turnover
tax led to protests by the brokers of stock exchanges
all over India. As a fallout of these protests, on
21st July 2004, the Finance Minister amended his proposals
by significantly lowering the tax burden and by proposing
a new STT regime with different tax rates for different
types of securities. Though this amendment has made
the stock market and day traders happy, it is likely
to result in significant revenue losses for the government.
Estimates suggest that the new STT will lead to a
revenue loss of Rs 6,000 to Rs 6,500 crores for the
fiscal year 2004-05. Given the fiscal constraints
faced by the government, it is difficult to understand
the rationale behind this tax rollback. Moreover,
as discussed in more detail later, the new STT is
more lenient towards non-delivery based short-term
trading and there is a possibility that it will encourage
speculative noise trading activities in the stock
market.
To put things into perspective, the imposition of
STT was not an isolated change. It was accompanied
by major reduction in the capital gains tax rate.
The finance minister proposed to abolish the current
10 percent tax on long-term capital gains from securities
transactions. In the case of short-term capital gains
from securities, he proposed to reduce the rate of
tax to a flat rate of 10 per cent . Currently, short
term gain is aggregated with taxable income from other
income classes and the short term capital gains tax
is levied at personal income tax rates. Against these
reductions in capital gains tax, he proposed to impose
the STT on transactions in securities on stock exchanges.
This tax was proposed to be levied at the rate of
0.15 per cent[1]
of the value of the security and would be payable
by the buyer of the security.
The benefits for imposing such a turnover tax, in
lieu of capital gains tax, are manifold. As Singh
(2004) discusses, the introduction of an
STT has the potential to curb excessive speculation
in the Indian stock market. Moreover, it was expected
that this new taxation policy would also help the
government to mobilize more revenue from the financial
investors.
However, the modified STT regime is considerably different
from the one proposed in the budget speech. The new
STT retains the 0.15 percent transaction tax only
on long term investors who take delivery of their
shares. Contrary to the original STT, in the new proposal
the buyer and seller will be splitting up the tax
burden equally between them. For day traders, arbitrageurs
and jobbers the tax rate has been brought down by
ten times from 0.15 percent to 0.015 per cent. Transaction
tax on derivatives has been brought down to 0.01 per
cent instead of the original proposal of 0.15 per
cent. Buying and selling of debt securities and bonds
including Government bonds have been totally exempt
from STT. It is interesting to note that though the
STT rates have been drastically revised downwards,
the finance minister has not reverted the capital
gains tax rates, which were lowered in the original
proposal.
One of the main reasons for imposing the STT was the
fact that most stock market players manage to avoid
or evade the capital gains tax. It was expected that
in a computerized system of stock market trading,
the transaction tax will act as a tamper proof and
low-cost method of collecting revenue from a section
of the population who pays relatively little tax.
However, the new STT brings the tax rates down by
a factor on ten for all short term and non-delivery
based trading in the market. This defies economic
logic as 55 to 60 percent of total stock market transactions
are short-term non-delivery based trade and because
of this reduction, the government is likely to face
a further resource crunch in the already constrained
fiscal situation. It is estimated that because of
the rollback of STT and the concurrent reduction in
capital gains tax rates, the total revenue earned
by the government from this instrument will come down
from Rs 7,000 crores to Rs. 1,000 crores only, causing
a massive shortfall of Rs 6,000 crores[2]
. It is not clear from where the finance minister
is going to cover this revenue loss. To put this shortfall
in perspective, the total allocation for rural employment
programmes in the Budget for 2004-05 is only Rs. 4,590
crores. From a principle of equity, it is difficult
to justify dolling out such fiscal largesse to a very
small group of relatively well-off people who are
involved in short term speculation[3].
It must be reiterated once again that long term investors
have not been given any new tax benefits in the modified
STT scheme.
This rollback of STT is going to take away most of
the other perceived benefits of the original STT system
as well. The new STT is essentially going to benefit
arbitrageurs and traders who indulge in very short
term speculative trading. This is likely to increase
the level of speculation in Indian stock markets.
Though it can be argued that speculation, which is
based on fundamentals, is essential for functioning
of the financial markets, it is well known that in
most stock markets, even in developed markets, fundamentals
play relatively little role in the determination of
stock prices[4].
This phenomenon is more widespread in developing country
markets where speculation and market manipulations
are more common. In India, repeated scams since 1992
have shown how stock market prices are manipulated
in this country. It will be extremely difficult for
anybody to argue that the wild mood swings of the
Sensex (Fig) can be explained by changes in the underlying
economic or financial fundamentals. In fact, to a
large extent, trading in the BSE is dominated by day
traders, who are essentially noise traders. Noise
traders are very short term speculators who trade
on thin margins and make their profits by trading
huge volume of securities. These transactions are
purely speculative, very short-term in nature and
are not based on economic or financial fundamentals
of the companies. It is unfortunate that the new STT
is going to benefit and promote precisely this type
of trading activity in the stock market. There is
a strong possibility that long-term investors will
be reluctant to enter the stock market if noise traders
can cause price of shares to decouple from their fair
value for long periods of time[5].
Increased speculative activity is also likely to increase
the volatility of share prices in India.
Chart
1 >> Click
to Enlarge
Apart from day traders, another category of investors
who are likely to benefit from the new tax structure
is the foreign institutional investors (FIIs). In
the previous tax regime, FIIs were required to pay
30 percent tax on short term capital gains and 10
per cent tax on long term capital gains. However,
the Double Taxation Avoidance Agreement (DTAA) between
India and Mauritius allows FIIs, who are registered
in Mauritius, to get away with much lower capital
gains tax rates. According to the DTAA, individuals
and companies that are residents of Mauritius will
pay their tax only in Mauritius and not in India.
Given the fact that Mauritius has no capital gains
tax, FIIs operating through that country effectively
do not pay any capital gains tax. However, these FIIs
are required to file their returns in India. The new
tax system will significantly reduce the tax burden
of the non-Mauritius based FIIs and will also reduce
the paperwork involved in filing capital gains tax
returns. The new tax structure also makes the Mauritius
route almost redundant and saves the FIIs from the
inconvenience of adding a layer to their operational
set up in that country. As additional sops to FIIs,
the investment ceiling for FIIs in debt funds has
been raised in the current budget to US$1.75 billion
from the existing ceiling of US$1 billion. The government
also proposes to make the procedures for registration
and operations of FIIs simpler and quicker to attract
greater inflow.
However, it is not clear why in every single budget
since 1992, FIIs are given special favours. FIIs are
already a dominant force in Indian stock markets.
Given the huge amount of foreign exchange reserves
available to India, the incremental benefit from increased
inflow of portfolio capital is minimal. In fact, recent
empirical evidence from a number of cross-country
studies has pointed out that among various forms of
foreign investments, foreign portfolio investment
is the least effective in promoting domestic investment
and growth. These studies reveal that the contribution
of portfolio investment to domestic capital formation
is lowest among different types of capital inflow.
Table 1 summarizes the main findings of some of these
studies.
Table
>> Click
to Enlarge
Also as Chandrasekhar
(2004) highlights, since 1992, India has
received an excess inflow of foreign portfolio investment
which is making macroeconomic management of the economy
extremely difficult. Given these problems with portfolio
investment, it makes little economic sense to keep
extending fiscal sops to portfolio investors.
To sum up the discussion, it can be said that the
original securities transaction tax (STT) was an innovative
idea to tax financial investors. It would have curbed
excessive speculative trading in Indian stock markets
and could have generated significant revenues for
the government. However, the finance minister's decision
to significantly alter the STT rates will now not
only allow a very high proportion of stock market
players to get away with paying very little tax but
it will also promote very short term and disruptive
speculative trading. In a year when the total allocation
for the National Common Minimum Programme has been
only Rs 10,000 crores, it is difficult to understand
why the finance minister relented to the pressure
from a few stock market players and effectively diluted
a major source of revenue earning for the government.
[1]
Short term capital gains from securities is defined
as profits made due to such sales within the year
[2] The Economic Times, 22 July 2004
[3] ''The brokers who were vocal last
week in their protests against the proposed 0.15 per
cent levy on daily turnover in securities transactions
have expectedly been identified as a group of 100-odd
arbitrageurs.'' -‘Sensexy, it's not – daily wagers
on the rampage', Nandu R Kulkarni in Mumbai, The Statesman,
July 12 2004. According to Sucheta Dalal: ''There
are 1,300 active brokers on the NSE and BSE's equity
segment and 75 in the debt market.'' In ‘Real impact
of transaction tax on people's life' Indian Express,
July 26th 2004.
[4]
For example, Shiller (1981,
1984) shows that changes in fundamentals could account
for only one-fifth of the high volatility in stock
prices. This observation is also supported by Campbell
and Shiller (1987), Fama and French (1988a, b), and
Poterba and Summers (1988).
[5]See
Noise
Trader Risk in Financial Markets' by De Long et.al
Bosworth
and Collins (1999), World Bank (1999) and World Bank
(2001)
|
|
Reference:
Bosworth, Barry, and Susan M. Collins. (1999): ''Capital
Flows to Developing Economies: Implications for Saving
and Investment.'' Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
1: 143–69.
Campbell, J. and R. Shiller. (1987): ''Cointegration
and Tests of Present Value Models.'' Journal of Political
Economy 95: 1062–87.
Bosworth
and Collins (1999), World Bank (1999) and World Bank
(2001)
Fama, E.F. & French, K.R. (1988a), ''Dividend Yields
and Expected Stock Returns'', Journal of Financial Economics,
Vol. 22, pp. 3-25.
Fama, E.F. & French, K.R. (1988b), ''Permanent and
temporary components of stock prices'', Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 96, No. 2, pp. 246-270.
Poterba, J.M. and Summers, L.H. (1988), ''Mean reversion
in stock prices: evidence and implications'', Journal
of Financial Economics, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 27-59.
Shiller, R.J (1984): ''Stock Prices and Social Dynamics.''
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 457–92.
Shiller, R.J. (1981): ''Do Stock Prices Move Too Much
to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?''
American Economic Review 71: 421–36.
World Bank (1999): Global Economic Prospects and the
Developing Countries: Beyond Financial Crisis, Washington.
D.C.
World Bank (2001): Global Development Finance 2001,
Washington. D.C.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|