Deep in the April issue
of the Reserve Bank of India's Bulletin are a couple of
statistics that policy-makers could use. In 2000-01,
exports as a proportion of sales among a sample of
400-odd foreign direct investment (FDI)-controlled firms
in India was just 11.6 per cent. And of the funds
utilised by these FDI companies, 40 per cent went into
acquisition of gross fixed assets such as plant and
machinery. Compare this with the corresponding ratios in
a similar RBI survey of nearly 2,000 public limited
Indian companies. In 2000-01, exports as a proportion of
sales was higher at 12.6 per cent and a much larger
proportion of funds, 48.9 per cent, was used for the
acquisition of gross fixed assets. In other words,
Indian companies are showing a greater export focus than
foreign firms and they are also investing more in plant
and machinery. This was not unique to 2000-01. The gap,
if anything, was larger in 1999-2000 and this was
probably the case right through the 1990s.
To put it simply, two of the fundamental reasons for the
wooing of FDI are not borne out by the experience of the
1990s. It is more than a decade since India dismantled
one of the most restrictive FDI regimes in the world and
replaced it with one of the most open and relaxed
national policies towards foreign investment among the
developing countries. Yet, even now the debate is about
how much more open India should be towards FDI. Earlier
this week, the Union Cabinet could not take a decision
on the proposal to raise the existing limits on FDI in a
number of sectors such as telecom, petroleum refining
and marketing. Caught between the xenophobes and
unthinking liberalisers, the policy on FDI has been
lurching in the wrong direction. It has been obsessed
with what can only be called the dollar and China
syndrome: why is India still receiving less than $ 4
billion of FDI every year and why is it attracting a far
smaller amount of FDI dollars than China?
The most visible impact of FDI in the manufacturing
sector has been in expanding the range of products
available to the consumers. This is so in cars,
two-wheelers, consumer durables, food products and
apparel. In services as well, a more open FDI regime has
seen the entry of more banks, new insurance companies,
while global management consultancies and accountancy
firms have virtually taken over the Indian market. But
do we know what FDI has done for fixed investment,
exports, and technological modernisation? Unfortunately
not, because the Government does not seem to be bothered
about the original rationale for FDI. A good example of
the warped contours of the Government discourse on FDI
is to be found in the Planning Commission (N. K. Singh)
committee on FDI whose recommendations seem to have
currently set the parameters for national policy in this
area and were the subject of debate in the Union Cabinet
earlier this week. Here was an opportunity to evaluate
FDI policy over the past decade and suggest measures
that would encourage investment that the economy could
do with. Instead, all that the committee did was focus
on what it thought the Government should do to meet a
(presumed) savings-investment gap during the Tenth Plan
of around $ 8.8 billion a year. That explains why all
the core proposals of the Planning Commission committee
were about a sweeping removal of sectoral caps in
infrastructure, manufacturing and financial services and
the removal of existing prohibitions in agriculture
(plantation) and real estate.
There was no discussion of why FDI has been showing less
interest in greenfield investment (the establishment of
new industrial and service units) than in using the
merger and acquisition (M and A) route to establish or
increase its presence in the Indian market.
There was no discussion of why much of the roughly $ 30
billion FDI that has come into the country since 1991
has been more interested in "tariff-jumping" into the
Indian market than in contributing to exports. There was
no discussion of what one can learn from the largest
case of FDI since 1991, which also turned out to be the
biggest fiasco — Enron. And there was no discussion of
why there has been such a limited ripple effect of the
technology that the FDI is supposed to have brought in
across the larger economy.
The case for the sweeping relaxation of the remaining
sectoral caps in FDI also rests on very flimsy grounds.
The Planning Commission committee argued that removal of
the remaining entry restrictions will remove "irritants
that are sometimes blown out of proportion by interested
parties to the detriment of national interest" (p39).
The report also refers (p84) to an un-named study which
suggested that the cap in telecom should be raised to 74
per cent, investment in petroleum retailing should not
be linked to refining and FDI should be allowed in
retail, real estate and commercial construction. It does
not take much to infer where such recommendations and
un-named studies come from. Besides holding discussions
with chambers of commerce and a few State Government
officials, the N.K. Singh group interacted with
multinational consultancies that have set up shop in
India. It does not mean that India's policy must be
tailored to suit these interests. The Planning
Commission group's own comparative analysis shows that
India has a more liberal FDI regime than Malaysia or
China. Yet, the two East Asian countries attract
considerably more investment than India in spite of the
Governments there following a hands-on approach and
having in place a positive rather than a negative list
(as in India) of sectors where FDI is allowed. As far as
the volume of FDI is concerned, it is clearly not the
presence or absence of FDI caps in each sector that
matter as much as the environment for investment. If a
liberal FDI policy is all that was important then the
sub-Saharan African countries, which by and large now
have the most open policy towards foreign investors in
the developing world, should be attracting huge volumes
of FDI.
The fundamental problem with FDI in India today is that
while before 1991 all of it went into greenfield
investment, it now appears to be increasingly
concentrated in the M and A route. A 2000 study by
Nagesh Kumar of RIS, Delhi, concluded that between 1997
and 1999, approximately 40 per cent of FDI was using the
M and A route to take over Indian companies, increase
control in existing subsidiaries by issuing shares at
low cost or buy back shares and de-list from the stock
exchanges.
In a new study of FDI in India, R. Nagaraj of the Indira
Gandhi Institute for Development Research has argued
that the problem is that our policy towards foreign
investors does not have a focus. In comparison with the
Chinese approach, the Indian FDI regime suffers because
it is passive (open to all, without any targeting) and
not strategic as in China. In the opinion of this
economist, India's FDI policy should aim at encouraging
investment in manufacturing for acquisition of
technology and for the establishment of international
trading channels to facilitate labour-intensive exports.
It cannot be that most of the FDI that has come into the
country has made no contribution to the economy. A
notable example of large-volume FDI that has had many
positive externalities is Hyundai Motors, which has
created substantial new investment, contributed to
modernisation of the auto ancillary industry and
exported volumes which are not insignificant. But
Hyundai and a few others are only notable exceptions.
The problem is that in dismantling the pre-1991
regulation of FDI, India has not just swung to the other
extreme.
The Government has set about creating a policy regime
that has neither coherence nor macro-economic purpose,
the only objective being to create what it thinks is a
set of incentives that will bring in large volumes of
FDI. |