The changes in minimum support prices for rabi season
crops illustrate the fact that the government is bent on pursuing an
infeasible strategy for resolving the
'food crisis' it has itself
engineered.
The recent announcement of the minimum support prices (MSP) for rabi
season wheat, oilseeds, pulses and barley reveal the rather convoluted
manner in which the government is attempting to muddle its way out of a'food crisis' of its own making. Going against the recommendations of the
Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP), the Food Ministry and
the Finance Ministry, which had argued for a freeze in the support price
for wheat, the Cabinet has increased the MSP for wheat by a small but
significant Rs. 10 per quintal to Rs. 620 per quintal. It has however
accepted the CACP recommendations to hike the MSP for oilseeds
(rapeseed/mustard and safflower), gram and masur by a substantial Rs. 100
per quintal to Rs. 1300, Rs. 1200 and Rs. 1300 respectively, while keeping
the MSP for barley at last year's level of Rs. 500 a quintal.
These changes have to be assessed in terms of their implications for the
resolution of the peculiar'
food crisis' confronting the government. This
takes the form of the accumulation of huge food stocks in the hands of the
Food Corporation of India (FCI) even when poverty, endemic hunger and
periodic reports of starvation deaths persist. In the case of wheat, the
new marketing season is expected to begin with stocks of 25 million
tonnes, as compared with the minimum required buffer stock at this time of
year of 4 million tonnes. Such large stocks in both wheat and rice have
proved wrong and aborted the government's policy of curtailing food
subsidies by raising the issue prices of food distributed through the
public distribution system. Rising MSPs that have ensured larger
procurement and rising issue prices that have reduced off
take from the PDS,
have together contributed to the burgeoning of stocks held by the FCI.
Since this increases the bill incurred by the FCI in the form of carrying
costs, the food subsidy has in fact increased, though it currently
finances meaningless stock accumulation rather than serving as a form of
support to the poor.
The congruence of opinion across the Food and Finance Ministries and the
CACP, regarding the need to freeze the MSP for wheat, comes as a response
to this crisis. Inasmuch as the freeze may help moderate the level of sale
by farmers to the procuring agencies, it is seen as one of the many means
required to bring down the embarrassing level of food stocks. However,
this superficial congruence conceals the fact that the demand for an MSP
freeze emanates from analysts with two different perspectives. There are
those who still believe that the provision of a cost-plus' remunerative'
floor to farmers is necessary to encourage productivity increases and
growth in the agricultural sector. In normal circumstances, they would
have supported an increase in MSP since, the low average rate of wholesale
price inflation notwithstanding, no one can deny that, in a period when
fertiliser subsidies are being phased out and power tariffs are being
raised, agricultural costs would have risen. If yet they support the
freeze, this is because in their view, the government's practice of
succumbing to pressure from the farm lobby and providing a
'bonus' over
and above the floor price recommended by the CACP has taken wheat and rice
prices to unwarrantedly high levels in recent years. The freeze is seen as
an effort to rollback the MSP to warranted levels, which would, hopefully,
reduce procurement.
There are, however, two problems with this argument that seeks to deal
with the problem of foodstocks by acting on the supply of food to the
procurement agencies. To start with, it leaves unresolved the question as
to how the existing high level of stocks at the start of the procurement
season can be reduced. But even if the problem created by pre-existing
stocks is ignored, the argument misses out on the possibility that any
cost-plus floor in the form of an MSP could result in procurement levels
that keep stocks high, given the current regime for disposing of those
stocks.
It is presumably the latter possibility that explains the CACP's decision
to recommend a substantial hike in MSP's for oilseeds and pulses that
would encourage a shift in acreage away from cereals to these kinds of
crops. While this may have a short-term impact on procurement and stock
levels, in the long run diversification ensured through the procurement
price mechanism would lead to the recurrence of the same problem. With
trade in agricultural commodities liberalised under the WTO, the high
floor price for oilseeds and pulses may lead to a situation where the
market is dominated by imported varieties that are cheap, rather than
domestic supplies procured at a cost-plus price and routed to the market
through the procurement system that would be expensive. The consequent
fall in offtake of domestic oilseeds and pulses may force the government
to hold large stocks of these commodities. The structure of official
stocks may change from cereals to other commodities, but stocks could
remain high keeping subsidies required to finance carrying costs high as
well.
This implies that the problems of existing and likely future accumulation
of food stocks cannot be dealt with from the side of supply, so long as
the procurement system is seen as a necessary support to Indian farmers,
which it is. Instead, the problems have to be dealt with from the demand
side. This requires not just the strengthening of the public distribution
system through which subsidised food should be supplied to all those
wanting to access such food supplies. It also requires a change in
mind-set. Food stocks need to be seen not as a liability created by the
procurement system but an asset, which should be put to use in
food-for-work programmes geared to enhancing rural and urban
infrastructure and increasing, thereby, productive employment and activity
and reducing poverty. This would have economy-wide effects as well that
would help restore industrial growth and contribute to an increase in
government revenues. It would also reduce the food stock “burden” and help
curtail subsides paid out in the form of carrying costs. Holding back on
such programmes on the ground that they would require rupee resources that
would widen the government's deficit is completely indefensible.
Failure to emphasise the demand-side solution to the problem of excess
stocks, strengthens the arguments of those who demand an MSP freeze merely
as the first step towards dismantling the procurement system by curtailing
its role only to that of garnering stocks adequate to maintain the minimum
buffer. This is seen as a logical corollary of trade liberalisation and
the effort to reduce the fiscal deficit. The needed reduction in stock
levels, needless to say, cannot be ensured through a minimum support price
programme accompanied by limited procurement, as some have suggested it
should, since that would make the decisions as to when, where and how much
to procure completely arbitrary and the system subject to misuse for
political patronage. Not surprisingly, many advocates of food stock, food
subsidy and fiscal deficit reduction have gone the whole way and suggested
that the system created after the agrarian crisis of the mid-1960s to
ensure that farmers are supported with a cost-plus,
'remunerative' floor
should be done away with.
While this would deal, most regressively, with the
'problem' of large food
stocks, by foreclosing supply to the government, it does not address the
problem of pre-existing stocks. Releasing a part of these stocks in the
market would depress prices to an extent that would render the effort to
dismantle the MSP-based system politically indefensible. It is for reason
that the government has been experimenting with the possibility of handing
over pre-existing stocks at extremely low prices to exporters. This
experiment with disposing off FCI stocks through exports began in November
2000, and 1.62 million tonnes of wheat were exported in 2000-01, and 3.18
million tonnes of wheat and 1.5 million tonnes of wheat have been
delivered for export till February 15 of the financial year 2001-02. In
this year's EXIM policy this drive is to be strengthened by subsidising
transport costs on food delivered for exports. As part of the ongoing
effort to do away with the MSP-based procurement system, which is partly
necessitated by the drive to reduce food subsidies provided to domestic
consumers, the government finds it necessary to subsidise consumers
abroad, at least for some time.
Fortunately, this whole misconceived effort is bound to prove politically
infeasible. When farmers in the US and the EU are being subsidised in
large measure through income support schemes of various kinds, a
government that is subjecting domestic producers to import competition can
hardly work to dismantle the little support it has provided its own
farmers. The fact that the government could not implement even the
recommendation that the MSP for wheat should be frozen because it has been
increased to higher than warranted levels in the recent past, shows that
in a period when huge concessions are being provided to domestic and
foreign industrial and financial capital, the demands of the agricultural
community cannot be completely ignored. Realising this, it would be best
for the government to work to ease the food stock crisis through feasible,
demand-side measures, in particular, through the launch of a massive
food-for-work programme. But if recent evidence of the government's
incompetence on matters of economic governance is an indication, good
sense is unlikely to prevail.