I am acutely conscious of
the great honour that has been bestowed on me in asking me to deliver
the Ansari Memorial Lecture this year at the Jamia Millia Islamia. It
is an honour as much because of the person being commemorated as because
of the list of distinguished speakers who have preceded me in commemorating
him. Dr.Ansari was a remarkable figure of the National Movement, whose
qualities of head and heart have been brought to light recently through
the labours of Professor Mushirul Hasan of this university. These lectures
instituted in his memory have, through the care of the organisers, been
able to draw some of the finest minds and have deserevedly become an
important event in the academic calendar of Delhi. I recall attending
one Ansari Memorial lecture, delivered by Professor Irfan Habib and
presided over by Professor Nurul Hasan, which was a source of great
pleasure and profit for me.
I
The topic I have chosen today
has to do with a basic divide in development economics. On the one side
are those who argue that the fetters on the development of the third
world come from its integration into the world capitalist system. This
does not mean that the internal structures of these economies play no
role in arresting their development, but these structures, even though
inherited from the past, are so enmeshed into their links with world
capitalism, i.e. the internal and external constraints upon their development
are so inextricably dialectically related, that distinguishing between
them is pointless. Underpinning this totality, shaping this overall
dialectic, however, is their link with world capitalism which is the
decisive element. As against this position, there are those who argue
that capitalism diffuses development, that, if the fruits of this process
of diffusion are not reaped in abundance by large segments of the third
world, the reason lies in their pre-existing social structure, which
is independent and sui generis, having nothing to do with their
integration into the world capitalist system. Indeed, on the contrary,
such integration can play the role of undermining the pre-existing structures,
and hence can usher in development by bending these structures themselves.
While some authors of this latter group would contest the proposition
that colonialism historically underlay the emergence of the phenomenon
of underdevelopment, others would not necessarily contest the issue
(or may even concede the point). They would however argue that the contemporary
world is very different from what prevailed historically, and that only
an "East India Company phobia" can blind us to this fact.
A divide along these lines
is present within the Marxist tradition as well. Indeed the classic
Marxist texts themselves can be cited in defence of positions on either
side of the divide. Thus Marx's remark that "the country that is
more developed industrially only shows, to the less developed, the image
of its own future" can be, and occasionally has been, cited in
defence of a "diffusionist" position. One can, quite justifiably
in my view, quarrel with this claim, on the grounds that both the historical
context of this remark (made with reference to Germany in relation to
England) as well as its theoretical context (referring to "immanent
tendecies" of capitalist relations wherever they are introduced
rather than to actual growth trajectories), are very different from
what this claim supposes. But, in the absence of any discussion of the
inequalizing effects of capitalism in the international arena
in the main body of Marx's work, a "diffusionist" interpretation
of this remark has tended to persist. Likewise, Marx's defence of free
trade on the grounds that it would hasten capitalist development and
hence accelerate progress towards socialism has tended to obscure the
international dichotomies spawned by capitalism. On the other side however
there are Marx's numerous remarks on colonialism, his reference to India
having "to pay 5 million pounds in tribute for 'good government',
interest and dividends of British capital", and his remark about
"exploitation" by a "conquering industrial nation",
implicit in which is the notion of one nation exploiting another.
Indeed, of the three main elements that we can note, following R.P.Dutt,
in Marx's writings on India (and hence by implication on the colonial
question), namely the destructive role of colonialism, the regenerative
role of colonialism, and the necessity of a political transformation
whereby the colonial people free themselves from imperialist rule, the
last one already presupposes an anti-"diffusionist" position.
One can cite remarks in support
of either side of the divide in Lenin's writings too. His statement
in Imperialism that "While.. the export of capital may tend
to a certain extent to arrest development in the capital-exporting country,
it can do so only by expanding and deepening the further development
of capitalism throughout the world" can be adduced in support of
a "diffusionist" position, of the view that imperialism tends
to "equalise" differences. On the other hand however the whole
thrust of Imperialism was to show how "Capitalism has grown
into a world system of colonial oppression and of the financial strangulation
of the overwhelming majority of the population of the world by a handful
of 'advanced' countries", to underscore inter alia in other
words the fundamental inequalities across countries that imperialism
was perpetuating and accentuating.
The element of ambiguity in
Marxist writings on the subject derives from an ambiguity with respect
to the precise relationship between the two basic types of revolution
that Marxism saw on the agenda, namely a socialist revolution in the
advanced countries and a democratic revolution in the third world. When
the former was prioritised, the implications of anti-"diffusionism"
receded into the background, and with it, to an extent, the very recognition
of it. On the other hand when the historical focus shifted from the
former towards the democratic revolution in the third world, theoretical
attention too was given, to a much greater extent, to the existence
and implications of international inequalities under capitalism. It
is significant that in both Marx and Lenin, the emphasis shifts towards
an anti-"diffusionist" stance in the course of their lives
as their attention shifts from Europe to the East as the potential theatre
of revolution. (Lenin's Imperialism represents that special moment
when a synchronisation of both types of revolution in a world conflagration
occasioned by the "general crisis of capitalism" appeared
to be on the historic agenda). It is also significant that the Marxist
theorist who sought to integrate colonialism into the very law of motion
of capitalism, Rosa Luxemburg, prioritisd the socialist revolution and
accepted a "diffusionist" position; her early death prevented
any possibility of disillusionment with the European revolution, and
hence of any shift in her position.
A clear anti-"diffusionist"
position was articulated for the first time at the Sixth Congress of
the Communist International, which argued that despite being integrated
into the world capitalist system, the backward economies had not witnessed
any significant development of the capitalist mode of production, and
of productive forces under the aegis of this mode of production: backward
economies' agriculture for instance was characterised as witnessing
a "pauperisation", rather than a "proletarianisation",
of the peasantry. In Marxist academic circles this position found
extensive articulation in Paul Baran's classic work The Political
Economy of Gowth which was published in 1957. Paradoxically however
precisely when the anti-"diffusionist" position appeared dominant
in Marxist, and wider academic, cirlces, its premises were being undermined.