Come
July and, unfailingly, Dataquest-one of two private agencies that are
sources of detailed information on India's IT sector-releases, over
consecutive issues, its data on performance of the IT industry for the
preceding financial year. Dataquest's information, unlike that of NASSCOM,
covers the whole of the IT sector, including hardware, software, software
services and IT-enabled services. It also provides detailed information
on the top 20 firms in the composite industry plus a limited amount
of information on the top 200.
That data suggests that during the years since 1991-92, when the Indian
software services industry and, to an extent, the hardware industry
was still in its infancy, there has been one striking structural feature
characterizing the sector. Over this 17-year period when industry revenues
have grown by more than 150 times or at a compound rate of 34 per cent
per annum, a few firms have routinely dominated the industry. Thus the
share of the top 20 firms in the industry throughout the period has
fluctuated between 47 and 57 per cent, standing at 55 per cent in 1999-2000
and at 56 per cent in 2006-07 (Chart 1). That is concentration as conventionally
measured has been high and relatively stable. What is more there is
evidence that at the core of the industry concentration is in fact increasing.
According to the results of Dataquest's most recent survey, the share
of the Top 20 firms in the revenues of the Top 200, which has been increasing
consistently over the last few years, rose sharply from 54 per cent
in 2005-06 to 64 per cent in 2006-07, as compared to a rise from 50
to 54 per cent between 2004-05 and 2006-07 (Dataquest, July 15, 2007).
Acquisitions such as that of i-Flex by Oracle and a sudden, sharp 136
per cent increase in the revenues of Tech Mahindra partly explain this
trend. But the fact of a high degree of concentration cannot be denied.
It is indeed true that the Top 20 list has seen the exit of some firms
over the years and the entry of others and the ranks of those that have
remained in the list for long have changed periodically. But even assessed
in these terms there are a number of firms that have been represented
in the Top 20 league for a significant number of years or over the period
as a whole. This should be clear from Table 1, which lists the Top 20
firms in 1999-2000 and 2006-07. During this period, while industry revenues
increased by close to 7 times at the compound rate of 32 per cent per
annum, well over half the firms remain in the Top 20 club either in
their original avatar or as entities that have merged with other members
in the list. There appears to be a degree of stability with respect
to industry leaders. Thus, a high degree of concentration combined with
relative stability at the top seems to be the picture that emerges.
And this is even more significant because Dataquest's figures relate
to the IT ''sector'', comprising of many industries as conventionally
defined.
Table 1: The Dataquest Top 20
1999-2000 |
2006-07 |
Wipro |
TCS
(including CMC) |
Tata
Consultancy |
Wipro |
IBM
India |
Infosys
Tchnologies |
Tech
Pacific |
HP
India |
Hewlett-Packard
India |
IBM
India |
NIIT |
Ingram
Micro |
Compaq
India |
Satyam |
HCL
Infosystem |
Redington
India |
Infosys
Technology |
HCL
Tech |
HCL
Technologies |
Oracle
India (including i-Flex) |
Redington
India |
Cognizant
Technology Solns |
Satyam
Computers |
Cisco
Systems |
Aptech |
Teledata
Informatics |
Samsung
India |
Intel
India |
Ingram
Micro |
HCL
Infosystems |
CMC
Ltd |
Tech
Mahindra |
Microsoft
India |
Patni
Computer Systems |
Tata
Infotech |
Microsoft
India |
Cognizant
Tech |
Lenovo
India |
Pentasoft
Tech |
Moser
Baer |
This
is surprising given the perception that low barriers to entry and rapid
technological change in the information technology sector make dominance
in terms of either technology or market share at any given point of
time an inadequate basis for monopoly. If firms have to remain competitive
they have to continuously innovate and beat the competition, which is
extremely difficult in an industry where technological advance is rapid.
This
view was first developed formally in Massachusetts Institute of Technology-economist
Franklin M. Fisher's expert testimony in favour of IBM during the thirteen-year
US vs. IBM antitrust battle that began in 1969 and ended with the case
being withdrawn on the grounds that it was without merit. Fisher and
his colleagues later elaborated IBM's case (Folded, Spindled and Mutilated:
Economic Analysis and U.S. v. IBM, 1983), which was built on the argument
that a company's share in its designated market at a given point of
time is no indication of either its market power or the presence of
significant barriers to entry into the industry. That argument rested
on grounds that in a technologically dynamic industry producing a heterogeneous
and differentiated product, a firm with an apparently large market share
could be subject to intense competition, because it operates ''in a
rapidly growing market in which superior new technologies succeeded
each other with breathtaking speed'' (Carl Kaysen's Foreword). Further,
the information technology industry is one in which customers were not
all small, individually powerless and poorly informed entities, but
large firms and government agencies that had the knowledge to assess
the appropriateness of prices charged and the ability to ensure alternative
sources of supply when exploited. History seems to have vindicated this
position held by the defense inasmuch as in time IBM lost its market
leadership in hardware supply and was finally forced to move out of
the hardware business. The decline in share partly provided the basis
for the withdrawal of the case against IBM 13 years after it was first
registered.
The argument that sheer size and overwhelming market share need not
be the result of anti-competitive practices, partly rested on the grounds
that they could be the outcome of behaviour, practices and strategies
that reflected 'superior skill, foresight and industry' rather than
the misuse of monopoly. These are practices that would be inevitable
for survival in an intensely competitive situation, necessitating innovation
and the transfer of the benefits of such innovations to customers in
the form of better products and lower prices. Only when this was not
true could the firm be seen as adopting anti-competitive practices.
Fisher et. al. identify three flaws in the arguments of the government
and those who held that IBM was a monopolist, based on evidence that
it controlled around 70 per cent of the market. The first was that the
boundaries drawn to identify the size of the ''market'', based on which
market share was calculated, were arbitrary. Second, was that they assumed
that ''anything'' which made it expensive or time-consuming to enter
an industry constituted a barrier to entry that facilitated monopolization.
And, third that they held that any price cutting by an incumbent firm,
especially if it was large, was a predatory practice revealing intent
to monopolize. Implicit in such views, according to them, was the wrong
notion that industries were normally on long-run equilibrium. Such a
notion they held was particularly wrong in a dynamic industry like the
computer industry, ''which has again and again experienced a totally
unexpected explosion of demand as new users of and new uses for computers
came into being. In such an industry, the competitive process-including
the special role of innovation-is what matters.
The view that it is misuse of monopoly rather than its presence was
the problem was strengthened during the anti-trust battle between Microsoft
and the Federal and various state governments in the US that began in
1997. At that time, Microsoft controlled the operating system running
on 90 per cent of personal computers and reportedly earned a profit
of around 40 cents per revenue dollar (Ken Auletta, Microsoft vs the
U.S. Government, and the Battle o Rule the Digital Age). Even here the
argument was not principally that Microsoft was using its dominance
over the operating systems (OS) market by exploiting barriers to entry
to overprice its product or slow the pace of technical advance. Rather,
the main issue (which emerged initially with respect to the Netscape
browser), was that Microsoft was ''leveraging'' monopoly in the OS market,
by bundling new products like Internet Explorer with its operating system
for free and forcing vendors to promote its browser, while concealing
the availability of alternatives. In the process it was seen as shutting
out competition in new areas to expand its monopoly and reducing consumer
choice. But there was no suggestion that Microsoft could slow or was
slowing the pace of technological change in its area of monopoly, and
yet remaining dominant.
Overall, therefore, the perception has been and remains that the information
technology sector is one where barriers to entry are limited and the
persistence of a large market share depends in the final analysis on
sustaining leadership through innovation. However, this view partly
begs the question. The difficulty with the analysis developed by Fisher
et. al. is that is it rests on three presumptions: (i) that monopoly
does not exist if that structure does not result in excess pricing and
stunted innovation; (ii) that if a sector is characterized by rapid
technological change it cannot be subject to barriers to entry, which
could either be technological or non-technological in character; and
(iii) monopoly exists when only one firm dominates the industry for
relatively long periods of time. An industry can be characterized by
concentration for long periods, with different firms accounting for
dominant market share at different points in time. Barriers to entry
need not mean that no firm can break into the market or expand if it
is not the leader, but that potential threats to incumbent firms can
only come from those which are large in size or have deep pockets, which
in turn makes it possible for them to buy or develop technologies that
can help them challenge and undermine incumbents. But if there are,
for various reasons, a degree of path dependence in the capacity to
deliver new innovations or bring them to market successfully, even technology
and deep pockets can favour the incumbent rather than a potential entrant.
Though IBM lost its position of dominance, it did remain in that position
for long. During its heydays, many of the leading innovations in the
computer industry came from IBM, and not everybody would be convinced
that this was purely because of 'superior skill, foresight and industry'.
The problem becomes even more complex when these ideas are applied to
an understanding of dominance in the Indian IT sector. It is easier
to apply them to the hardware segment, where the growing presence and
dominance of international brands in the post-liberalization period
points to the fact that even where new entrants had the opportunity
to grow and develop technological capabilities in a regime of protection
before facing competition, the global industry leaders can easily displace
them. It obviously applies to the packaged software industry where few
Indian firms have made a mark, where global leaders dominate the domestic
market, and many of the few indigenously-developed software ''products''
are losing out in their relevant markets. But how do we explain persisting
dominance in the software services sector? Here dominance lies not in
the market, which is situated abroad and is so large that, despite India's
scorching pace of growth, Indian firms still account for an extremely
small market share. The dominance lies in the fact that among the large
number of domestic players catering to this market, a few (such as TCS,
Wipro and Infosys) account for a large share-much larger than the aggregate
industry figures suggest. It is dominance over supply rather than dominance
in the market that needs to be explained.
Such dominance cannot be explained by technological leadership since,
as widely accepted, India's presence is still largely in (technologically)
lower-end software services. This is not an area where technology can
constitute a barrier to entry. The explanation possibly lies in the
ability of leading firms to excel in what Fisher et. al. refer to as
''other forms of innovation''. This involves, to start with, ''process
innovation'', or ''a reorganization of the way in which production is
structured'', leading to more efficient ways of services provision and
better global delivery models. A second form of such innovation is ''the
creation of a management system that keeps decisionmakers in touch with
the marketplace and links that awareness with the design and manufacturing
activities'' as well as permits quick responses to customer demands
and rapid technological change.
It should be obvious that unlike process innovation in commodity production,
this type of process innovation in services provision is less transparent
and not easily identified. Yet, it obviously exists and matters, as
suggested by the various forms of certification that have been in use
in the software services industry. But what is surprising is that the
adoption of these practices, and the process of building an ''image''
or ''brand'' for being a firm which does so, has operated as a barrier
to entry to smaller firms, resulting in persisting dominance of a few.
Even here history, preexisting market size and deep pockets seem to
matter.