One of the unfortunate tendencies that developed among many official
publications brought out by the economic Ministries of the Government of
India over the 1990s, was the tendency to paint a rosy picture of the
economy, and especially of the effects of the liberalising "economic
reform" process. This tendency extended to underplaying glaring problems
such as inadequate employment generation, and selectively presenting data
and choosing time periods to establish more positive trends even when they
did not really exist.
Apart from the "public relations" implications, it is not clear what
advantages there were of such a tendency, even for the Government itself.
After all, effective policy interventions of whatever type need to be made
on the basis of informed assessment, and when the actual economic reality
is sought to be disguised or incompletely described this makes the task of
policy makers even more difficult. This tendency did not just make
publications like the Finance Ministry's annual "Economic Survey" much
less useful, it also contributed to reducing the credibility of official
publications in general.
Fortunately, the Reserve Bank of India in recent times has shown itself to
be much less influenced by this tendency. While it is true that in terms
of policy prescriptions the RBI more or less sticks to the neoliberal
paradigm currently prevailing in official circles, it has been more
objective in its reporting at least of the basic economic reality. But
this in turn makes the latest Annual Report of the RBI very depressing
reading, since it describes a situation of deceleration of growth in the
major productive sectors along with greater financial fragility.
Furthermore, it becomes clear (although is not stated so explicitly in the
Report) that this is not accidental or conjunctural, but is very much a
result of the economic strategy of the past decade.
Chart 1 describes the growth rates (in real terms) of the major sectors in
the past three years. Not only is the target rate of 7 per cent per annum
far from being met, but it is evident that there is all-round deceleration
especially in the last year. The RBI in fact makes a stronger statement :
"Filtering the data on real GDP growth to eliminate irregular year-to-year
fluctuations indicates the presence of a growth cycle in the Indian
economy and a discernible downturn in the second half of the 1990s."
(Summary, page 17, emphasis added.) This brings the average growth rate of
the "growth cycle" over the 1990s to only 4.4 per cent, and also suggests
that the process of liberalising reform has not delivered the higher rates
of growth that were promised and anticipated.
Not surprisingly, these lower rates of GDP growth have also been
associated with lower rates of aggregate savings and investment. Chart 2
indicates the extent of reduction in aggregate savings and investment
rates even over the course of the 1990s. While the decline is not a huge
one, it marks a break from the overall trend increase in savings and
investment rates that is evident over the five decades since Independence,
whereby these rates rose with increases in per capita income. Of course,
such a decline over the past few years reflects the depressed private
expectations emanating from the general slowdown in economic activity,
along with the very related substantial declines in public sector savings
and investment.
But there are other causes for concern in the composition of savings and
investment in the recent past. It is evident from Chart 3 that private
household savings of both financial and physical forms, has come to
dominate savings. This includes all physical savings by non-corporate
bodies, including the increase in physical assets of small-scale
industries and agricultural units, and so to some extent represents a
dynamism of the these sectors which must be welcomed. But to the extent
that it also incorporates increase physical assets of households which are
not designed to be part of productive assets (such as residential houses
and passenger cars), it may in fact reflect an increase in consumption
rather than saving per se. Also, the complete collapse of public sector
saving, to the point where it has become a net dissaver, deserves serious
attention.
These trends have their counterparts in the composition of gross domestic
capital investment as described in Chart 4. Even over the 1990s, while
the share of the private corporate sector has remained the same, that of
the public sector as fallen quite substantially in a relatively short
time. The household sector has emerged by the end of the decade as the
dominant sector in gross domestic investment.
As was evident already from Chart 1, the primary sector has experienced
the sharpest deceleration in growth terms in recent years. This is part of
a longer term tendency which has meant that there has been a very
significant deceleration in the average annual growth rate of the all-crop
index of agricultural production from 5.2 per cent in the 1980s to only
2.3 per cent in the 1990s.
Further, the RBI notes that during the second half of the 1990s the
volatility of agricultural production has increased. The high volatility
is clear from Chart 5, and is quite sharp for both foodgrain and non-foodgrain
crops. The poor performance of agriculture is attributed by the RBI to
"low and variable growth of output, poor and declining yields, inadequacy
of capital formation and infrastructure and degradation of natural
resources due to inefficient cropping patterns (which) have emerged as the
major obstacles to rapid and sustained growth." (Summary, page 2)
However, the factors which are in turn behind these agricultural trends
are not adequately captured by the RBI report. These factors are very much
part of the overall policy environment which characterised the 1990s.
Thus, one important factor behind the drop in foodgrain output growth is
the drastic decline in real public investment that has occurred in
agriculture over a long period. The deceleration had started during the
1980s, but the 1990s have furthered that trend. In addition, the 1990s
have witnessed a decline in other infrastructure development in the rural
areas, which had increased somewhat in the earlier period. Further, the
strategies of reducing subsidies on fertiliser and attempting to increase
user charges on water, electricity and other farming inputs which a number
of state governments have tried to implement, have also raised costs for
farmers and in some cases led to reduced use of commercial inputs.
Of course, the most glaring problem in the food economy of India at the
moment is the presence of huge excess stocks of foodgrain with the Food
Corporation of India, which are now as high as 62 million tonnes, up by
more than three times in just six years. These are not being effectively
utilised either to reduce hunger in areas and among populations which are
food deficit, or to promote public works which in turn would develop
infrastructure. Chart 6 makes it clear that this is a reflection of the
peculiar combination of increased procurement despite lower harvests and
lower off-take by consumers from the Public Distribution System. And this
too, is very much a creation of economic policies of the past few years,
rather than an arbitrary process.
Thus, one important reason for the lower off-take was the decision taken
in the 2000-01 Budget to increase the prices of grain available in the
Public Distribution System to the so-called "economic cost" of the FCI for
the Above Poverty Line (APL) population and to half that cost for the
Below Poverty Line (BPL) population. This resulted in a sharp decline in
sales especially in the Targeted PDS. But, as the RBI Report points out,
the expansion of buffer food stocks to 3 times the desired level has been
accompanied by a decline in per capita availability of foodgrain in the
economy as a whole. This fell from a high of 505.5 grams per day in 1997
to 470.4 grams in 1999 and then to 458.6 grams in 2000, indicating that
the basic food security problem, far from being solved, has actually
worsened.
Simultaneously, the economic conditions of most cultivators has
deteriorated because the falling international prices of most agricultural
commodities in a context of more open trade in these goods has combined
with higher input prices to squeeze cultivating margins. Falling market
prices have meant that more cultivators have chosen to sell to official
procurement bodies, thus adding even more to the excess food stocks.
Throughout the liberalising reform process, it has been clear that the
industrial sector is much more important for government strategy than the
agricultural sector, despite the fact that most of the labour force still
remains in agriculture. But even industrial growth has shown signs of not
just deceleration but actual recession over the past few years. While the
manufacturing recession was evident from late 1996, there were
expectations of a recovery based on a slight increase in growth rates over
1999. However, as Chart 7 makes abundantly clear, these hopes of a quick
recovery have been belied and the last year's industrial performance shows
deceleration once again. Indeed, the quarterly data show a more worrying
pattern of deceleration over each quarter in recent times, suggesting a
deepening of recession.
Chart 8 indicates that capital goods and basic goods are the worst
performing sectors in the recent period. This of course reflects the
slowdown in investment, in turn reflecting the depressed private
expectations in a context of recession and reduced public investment. But
of course this is also bad news for the future prognosis for industry as a
whole, which would be affected by the slowdown in these sub-sectors.
Durable consumer goods have performed the best among al the sub-sectors of
manufacturing. Once again, this has been affected by very specific
policies of the government such as the Pay Commission award which allowed
for more purchase of such goods by a segment of public sector employees,
and the special protection afforded to the automobile industry in the face
of wider import liberalisation for a range of final consumer goods.
Non-durable consumer goods, which include many items of mass consumption,
have been growing very slowly throughout this period, reflecting the very
limited expansion of a mass market through the liberalisation process.
In this context, it comes as no great surprise to note, from Chart 9, that
the infrastructure industries have also performed relatively poorly. To a
large extent this reflects the inadequacy of public investment and
maintenance over this period, but the slowdown in growth of effective
demand has also played a role. In addition to a low average rate of
growth, most of these sectors have displayed very high volatility and
fluctuation in growth rates even over a relatively short time period.
The government's obsession with fiscal correction is well known, even
though its declared intentions have tended to be far more draconian and
"fiscally disciplined" than its actual fiscal performance. The 1990s were
marked by frequent references to the need to rein in the fiscal deficit as
the major, even primary, goal of the government. Of course such an
obsession was problematic at several levels, not least of which was the
tendency to conflate the capital expenditure part of the fiscal deficit
(which implied important public infrastructure spending which could be
crucial for future growth) with the revenue deficits which reflected the
excess of current spending over current receipts.
But the concern with controlling the large fiscal deficit becomes
completely ridiculous in a period of economic recession, which is also
characterised by large and growing foreign exchange reserves and large and
growing public holding of food stocks. It would be difficult for anyone to
argue that a more aggressive fiscal stance would be inflationary in such a
context, and hard to deny that this would play a positive role in moving
the economy out of recession. But this, nevertheless, is what the
government continues to maintain : that the need of the hour is continued
or even greater fiscal rectitude, regardless of the cost in terms of
reduced levels of economic activity
What is interesting to note is that, despite all this emphasis on fiscal
discipline, the 1990s showed very little tendency towards fiscal
correction overall. Chart 10 shows the fiscal and revenue deficits as
shares of GDP over the 1990s, divided into three sub-periods. The fiscal
deficit here is calculated according to the new definition adopted by the
Central Government since the 1999-2000 Budget, that is, excluding the
share of small savings that go to the State Governments.
The first sub-period is of course inflated by the effect of the crisis
year 1990-91, when the fiscal deficit was as high as 6.6 per cent of GDP.
Nevertheless, it turns out that the first sub-period shows an average
level of fiscal deficit to GDP ratio (at 5.4 per cent) that is only
marginally higher than the latest sub-period, when the average was 5.1 per
cent of GDP. And what is worse, this was dominantly in the form of the
revenue deficit, which climbed to the very high levels of 3.5 per cent of
GDP for the period 1997-98 to 2000-01.
The counterpart of this, of course, was the collapse in capital
expenditure which has already been noted. Central Government capital
expenditure, shown in Chart 11, declined to only 1.15 per cent of GDP, not
just well below the levels at the beginning of the decade, but many
multiples less than the rate of 4 per cent achieved in the 1980s. And
developmental expenditure of the Central Government, which also includes
the items described as "social expenditure" also fell continuously over
the 1990s, to levels of less than 7 per cent for the last years of the
decade.
If the fiscal deficit has remained "high" despite such falling public
expenditure of the socially desirable variety, it is largely because
interest payments constitute a growing and dominant part of expenditure,
accounting for nearly half of current revenues. And this in turn is not
because of the burden of past debt alone, but more importantly because of
financial liberalisation measures which have forced the government to take
greater recourse to open market borrowings and raised the cost of
financing the deficit. Chart 12 shows how the share of the fiscal deficit
being financed by market borrowing has ballooned from less than 18 per
cent at the beginning of the decade to nearly 70 per cent by the year
2000-01. This nit only means that less of government expenditure has
positive linkage and multiplier effects which could generate more economic
activity, but it also and naturally makes the task of actual fiscal
correction that much more difficult.
Of course, the RBI document must inevitably be more concerned with
monetary policy and financial issues than with the real economy, and most
of the Annual Report is indeed devoted to these matters. But because it
has been quite frank and realistic about the nature of the problems
confronting the real economy, it provides more valuable insights than most
official publications that are actually concerned with describing the real
economy. And the picture that it presents is one that calls for an urgent
and thorough reconsideration of the current economic strategy.
|