An
often-noted feature of the Indian economy is a lack of correspondence
between trends in shares in GDP of the principal sectors and their
shares in employment. In particular, while the share of the agricultural
sector in GDP has fallen over time, the proportion of the population
earning a livelihood in the rural areas has more or less stagnated. One
obvious reason for this is the failure of urban economic activity, in
particular organised manufacturing, to absorb labour to any substantial
degree. In fact, rural-urban migration even to the extent that it has
occurred has been accompanied by a burgeoning of the urban non-formal
sector, as we note below.
However,
what is even more disconcerting is that agriculture too has been losing
its capacity to absorb labour in adequate measure. In fact, an analysis
of the National Sample Survey data on agriculture not only points to a
deceleration in the rate of growth of agricultural workers during the
1990s, but for some time now analysts have reported a decline in the
elasticity of employment in agriculture with respect to output.
Based
on such evidence, it has been argued that rural non-agricultural
employment must be promoted both as the principal means of absorbing
surplus rural labour and as a vent for such surplus labour within the
rural sector itself. Not surprisingly, when the NSSO’s surveys of
employment relating to 1972-73, 1977-78, 1983 and 1987-88, pointed to a
sharp rise in the share of rural non-agricultural employment in total
rural employment (especially in the case of males), many analysts
welcomed the trend as a positive development that needed to be
sustained. The reversal of that trend between 1987-88 and 1993 and its
revival subsequently, have also been a matter of much debate.
The
positive assessment of the growth of rural non-farm activity stems from
the perception that under certain conditions there can exist rural
linkages of a kind that permit a ‘holistic’ development of the rural
areas so that the concomitant of agricultural growth, which generates
additional incomes and new demands, some of which can be met with local
resources and skills, is a process of occupational diversification in
the rural sector itself. This reduces the dependence on the development
of urban centres for generating a significant quantum of employment
outside agriculture and offers an alternative to the ‘dualism’
characteristic of development in the present-day developing world.
In
practice, however, there are a number of constraints to the realisation
of such a process of rural development. Principally, increases in rural
incomes lead to an increase in demand for manufactures of a kind
produced in factories located at urban centres. This would be
particularly true either when per capita incomes exceeds some critical
minimum level or when income inequalities ensure that increases in
income tend to be concentrated more among the well to do sections of the
population. This implies that non-farm activities in the form of rural
manufacturing would be more the exception than the rule.
The
evidence suggests that rural industries and services are of many kinds.
The three main forms of rural industry remain: (i) the production of low
quality and cheap varieties of goods meeting certain kinds of needs
using locally available raw materials (for example, beedi-making, bamboo
work and earthenware production); (ii) agro-processing such as rice
milling and production of puffed rice; and (iii) the transitional
location of modern industry in rural areas which leads over time to
these areas being absorbed as urban centres. (The only exceptions to
this are crafts like handlooms, which historically have tended to be
concentrated in certain centres).
As
far as the first of the above-noted versions of rural industry is
concerned, it reflects the low level of per capita income among the
lower income deciles of the population in a region, which has prevented
the diversification of their demand in favour of modern manufactures.
The number of such deciles would of course depend on the average level
of per capita incomes in the region and the degree of inequality.
However, given the fact that modern factory-based production does not
tend to be located too close to sources of demand, but rather
compensates for higher transportation costs through the higher
productivity and better quality associated with mass production, we
should expect that as the share of the population whose real per capita
income exceeds a critical minimum increases, there would be a tendency
for rural-based manufacture of basic consumption goods to actually
decline, with an associated decline in the employment generated by such
activities.
Unlike
in the case of manufactures, any increase in the productivity and degree
of commercialisation of agriculture and/or increases in incomes from
other sources in rural areas is bound to be accompanied by an increase
in demand for construction services, repair services, consumer services
of various kinds, transportations services and services in the
communication and storage areas, which are best met with locally-based
labour. Hence an increase in the share of employment and output of these
sectors would be an inevitable corollary of improved rural incomes.
The
difficulty is that the reverse need not be true. That is, an increase in
employment in services need not be a reflection of an increase in rural
incomes. This is because non-farm employment in services can be the
result of a distress-driven spill-over into non-farm activities of a
labour force that is faced with inadequate opportunities in crop
production. Thus a complex of factors rather than the mere effect of a
slow or fast growth in agriculture appear to explain trends in non-farm
rural economic activity. Assessing any trend in rural non-agricultural
employment requires therefore an examination of the structure of
non-farm activity and its evolution.
The
availability of the results of the Fourth Economic Census relating to
1998, and the comparability of figures yielded by the three censuses
relating to the years 1980, 1990 and 1998 provides such an opportunity.
The Censuses provide information on the number of and employment
in enterprises engaged in all activities outside crop production and
plantations in both urban and rural areas. They however include figures
on a number of activities allied to agriculture such as livestock
production and agricultural services including hunting, trapping and
game propagation, forestry, logging and fishing. These are identified as
agricultural activities in the Economic Censuses. These activities have
been registering an increase in importance in the rural areas. As Charts
3 and 4 indicate the share of these activities as captured by both their
share in the number of rural enterprises and their share in rural
employment outside of crop production and plantations has risen
consistently leading to a decline in the share of non-agricultural
activities between 1980 and 1998. This points to a shrinking of the
relative role of “typical” non-farm activities in rural economic
activity.
This
shrinkage of the relative role of what are considered typical
non-agricultural activities could have been interpreted as an indication
of rural dynamism in the form of the diversification of agricultural
activity but for other disconcerting trends revealed by a comparison of
the Economic Censuses. The first striking trend revealed by the figures
reported in Charts 1 and 2 is a deceleration in activity in the non-crop
producing and non-plantation segments of both urban and rural economy.
To start with the urban areas, the evidence points to a decline in the
growth of the number of non-farm enterprises from an annual average rate
of 3.6 per cent to 2.5 per cent between 1980-90 and 1990-98, and a sharp
decline in the number of workers in the non-farm sector from 3.2 to 1.4
per cent. This points to a deceleration in the expansion of employment
in the urban sector. While a part of this may be because of improvements
in productivity and the movement of child workers into education, the
sharpness of the fall does point to inadequate employment growth in
urban non-farm activity.
When
combined with the evidence on the falling elasticity of employment
growth with respect to output growth in the agricultural sector referred
to earlier, these urban trends increase the significance of rural
non-farm activity. However, even here there are clear signs of
deceleration. The average annual rate of growth of the number of rural
enterprises only fell marginally from 2.7 per cent during 1980-90 to 2.3
per cent during 1990-98. However, the rate of growth of workers engaged
in non-farm activity in the rural areas fell from 3.3 per cent to 2.3
per cent during these two periods. This suggests that the expansion of
non-farm activity has occurred through the growth of a number of smaller
enterprises, suggesting that at least some of this expansion could be
the result of a distress-driven shift to non-agricultural activity.
In
fact, as Chart 5 makes clear, the growth of non-farm activity has not
been accompanied by the growth of small capitalist enterprises based on
hired labour, which would also be indicative of dynamic diversification
of economic activity. Rather, the share of own-account enterprises (OAEs)
or enterprises that do not use hired labour has remained constant at
around 77 per cent of all non-farm enterprises in rural areas right
through the 1980s and 1990s. Interestingly, even in the urban areas the
share of OAEs has declined by just 4 percentage points between 1980 and
1998 and still remains at the relatively high of 62 per cent of all
urban non-farm enterprises even in 1998.
Another
indicator of the nature of evolution of the structure of economic
activity, is the industry-wise distribution of non-farm activity. As
Chart 6 shows, three kinds of ‘industries’ dominated rural non-farm
activities during the period under study: manufacturing, the wholesale
and retail trade, and community, social and personal services, which
together accounted for around 90 per cent of non-farm enterprises.
However, there have been significant changes in the shares of these
three sectors over the 18 years that the three censuses under discussion
spanned. The share of manufacturing enterprises in all non-agricultural
enterprises fell from 39 per cent in 1980 to 25 per cent in 1998, while
that of trading enterprises increased from 31 to 38 per cent and of
enterprises engaged in community, social or personal services from 21 to
26 per cent. Thus, it was not areas like storage, transportation, and
repair services, where growth would be triggered by agricultural
dynamism, that non-farm activities expanded, but in areas like trade and
social and personal services.
It
could be argued that it is not the expansion in the number of
enterprises but in employment that matters, but as chart 7 relating to
1998 shows, the domination of the three sectors mentioned above was even
greater in employment than in the number of enterprises and
manufacturing’s share in employment was not way out of line from its
share in non-farm enterprises.
The
domination of trade and service activities in rural non-farm employment
is accompanied by a domination of small enterprises in non-farm
activity. Own account enterprises that do not employ hired workers
accounted for 47 per cent of all non-agricultural activity in 1998 and
non-directory establishments or those employing less than six workers
(hired and non-hired) for another 21 per cent (Chart 8). Medium sized
capitalist enterprises with more than six workers accounted for just 32
per cent of total employment. What is more, even in urban areas, OAEs
and NDEs accounted for 50 per cent of non-agricultural employment in
1998 (Chart 9).
Finally,
if we examine the distribution of non-agricultural workers by
enterprises classified according to size class of employment, we find
that even in 1998 small enterprises overwhelmingly dominated the total
number of enterprises and substantially dominated in terms of share in
workers. Enterprises
employing less than 6 workers accounted for 84 and 79 per cent
respectively of rural and urban non-agricultural enterprises and 41 and
33 per cent of rural and urban non-agricultural workers (Chart 10 and
11).
How
is all this information to be interpreted? First, the evidence seems to
suggest that the kind of diversification conventionally associated with
capitalist development has not occurred in India even after five decades
of post-Independence development. That process of diversification in the
developed countries was captured by Kuznets as involving “the shift
away from agricultural to non-agricultural pursuits” and only recently
“away from industry to services”, besides “a change in scale of
productive units, and a related shift from personal enterprise to
impersonal organisation of economic firms, with a corresponding change
in the occupational status of labour.” Here, the shift to services has
occurred well before manufacturing matured, and the shift to larger
scale and impersonal forms of organisation has been extremely gradual.
Second,
there are signs that even this gradual process of diversification of
economic activity has lost momentum during the 1990s.
Third,
the structure of non-agricultural activity in the rural areas and its
evolution suggests that the pace and pattern of growth of agriculture
has not adequately contributed to a “dynamic” diversification of
rural non-agricultural activity.
Finally,
semi-capitalist forms of organisation and smaller scale units still
dominate the non-agricultural sector in both urban and rural areas to an
extent where they appear indicative of structural stagnation in
India’s development.
|