The
evidence of an acceleration in GDP growth in India increases, aided
on occasion by periodic revisions in the base year used for constructing
the estimates. While the factors accounting for this acceleration are
still being debated, another unusual feature of this growth since the
1980s has received less attention: the growing disproportionality between
agricultural and non-agricultural growth. Using GDP figures with 1993-94
as base, S. Sivasubramonian estimates that the rate of growth of GDP
in the agricultural and allied sectors rose from 1.5 per cent during
1970/71-80/81 to 3.43 during 1980/81-90/91, and then declined to 2.97
per cent during 1990/91-99/00. Over the same periods the rate of growth
of non-agricultural GDP accelerated from 4.38 per cent to 6.37 per cent
and 7.14 per cent respectively (Chart 1). (The figures for output in
the form of ''services of dwelling'' are separated out from that of
the non-agricultural sector for these calculations.)
What
is particularly remarkable is that the acceleration of non-agricultural
growth during the 1990s was accompanied by a decline in the rate of
agricultural growth. The disproporationality is visible even when the
comparison is restricted to industrial and agricultural growth (Table
1). Figures for the initial years of this decade indicate that this
disproportionality in growth has only increased since.
Table
1: Annual Trend Rates of Growth |
|
Total |
Manf. |
Min.&
Qu. |
Elect. |
Foodgrain |
Non-Food |
All
Agricul. |
1950-51
to 64-65 |
7.2 |
7.1 |
5.9 |
13.6 |
3.0 |
3.9 |
3.3 |
1965-66
to 79-80 |
4.7 |
3.8 |
6.9 |
6.2 |
3.0 |
2.6 |
2.9 |
1965-66
to 74-75 |
4.3 |
2.7 |
9.4 |
3.8 |
3.4 |
3.0 |
3.2 |
1975-76
to 84-85 |
4.9 |
4.3 |
6.6 |
7.3 |
2.5 |
2.9 |
2.6 |
1985-86
to 94-95 |
6.2 |
6.2 |
4.2 |
8.3 |
3.1 |
5.7 |
4.1 |
1994-95
to 03-04 |
5.7 |
6.1 |
2.6 |
5.3 |
0.6 |
-0.6 |
0.1 |
Source:
Computed from Index of Industrial Production Data, collated from RBI,
Handbook of Statistics
on Indian Economy.
These
sectoral trends suggest that domestic agricultural growth is now not
a constraint on the growth of the non-agricultural sector. This does
mark a structural shift in the pattern of growth, when compared with
the first three decades of post-Independence development, when the agricultural
bottleneck was seen as an important factor responsible for the failure
of the strategy of development based on the Mahalanobis model. The argument
was that the Mahalanobis strategy underestimated the agricultural constraint
by treating agriculture as a bargain sector in which output growth could
be accelerated without much investment, by making suitable institutional
adjustments.
There were three forms of intersectoral linkages between the agricultural
and non-agricultural sectors that were seen as important. First, with
the agricultural sector accounting for 61 per cent of non-residential
GDP in 1950/51 (at constant 1993-94 prices) and 76.2 per cent of employment,
demand from the agricultural sector was seen as crucial to sustaining
the demand for non-agricultural products and services, especially manufactured
products. Second, since agricultural commodities constituted a significant
share of input costs in some industries and of the wage basket in most,
increases in agricultural prices were variously analysed as affecting
industrial production. In particular, if an industry was agro-based
or was characterised by a tendency for money wages to rise with increases
in the prices of wage goods, it would experience an increase in costs
that may not be neutralised by an increase in final product prices.
In the event, profits could be squeezed and manufacturing investment
affected adversely. Thirdly, increases in agricultural prices would
constrain the growth of demand in the manufacturing sector, since consumers
would allocate a larger share of their incomes to food consumption and
a smaller share to manufactures demand and the government may reduce
public expenditure to reduce absorption and dampen price increases.
This constraint on demand growth would also adversely affect the ability
of firms in industries producing mass consumption goods to raise prices
in order to cover higher costs.
These different ways in which agricultural performance was expected
to affect non-agricultural growth were predicated on the operation of
two transmission mechanisms: first, increases in non-agricultural growth
were expected to result in increases in the direct (inputs) and indirect
(wage goods) demand for agricultural products. Second, since, agricultural
growth was seen as constrained from the supply side, any disproportionality
in industrial and agricultural growth was expected to result in an abnormal
increase in the prices of agricultural goods, since those prices were
largely determined by the relative levels of supply and demand.
In the aftermath of the agricultural crisis of the mid-1960s, this problem
was compounded by the fact that the provision of support to agricultural
production in the form of cost-plus remunerative prices, offered a floor
price that encouraged speculation. This was because if speculative hoarding
was not followed by the expected increase in prices, stocks could be
disposed at the cost-plus support price, which reduces the risk of large
losses. As a result, increases in demand relative to supply inevitably
raised prices, whereas increases in supply in years of a good harvest
did not result in any significant decline in market prices.
It needs to be noted that these mechanisms are operative only if there
are limits on altering domestic supply with imports. If foreign exchange
can be accessed easily to finance such imports, the structure of domestic
supply need not be largely determined by the structure of domestic production.
Commodities in whose case domestic demand exceeds supply based on domestic
production could be imported to hold down the price level. During the
1950s and early 1960s, India faced a binding balance of payments constraint,
since access to foreign exchange was limited too export revenues, limited
FDI inflows and flows of capital through the bilateral and multilateral
aid network. Yet, the economy witnessed rapid non-inflationary growth
in manufacturing even when agricultural growth was moderate because
of access to food imports through the P.L. 480 route, which enhanced
supplies and helped dampen price increases. It was when access to such
imports tapered off that the agricultural constraint proved binding,
leading to the deceleration of manufacturing growth during the late
1960s and 1970s.
It is in this background that we need to assess the changed circumstances
of the 1980s and 1990s, especially the latter decade, when the disproportionality
in non-agricultural and agricultural growth widened considerably, without
triggering inflation and limiting non-agricultural growth on account
of an inflationary barrier. In fact, changes in the environment and
pattern of growth triggered tendencies that prevented the realisation
of the denouement expected based on the late-1960s and 1970s experience.
The relevant change in the environment was the transformation of the
world of international finance that, for the first time, provided ''emerging
markets'' like India access to private international finance. It is
now widely held that the Indian government exploited that opportunity
during the 1980s, to overcome the development impasse of the 1970s.
Deficit-financed expenditure was used to accelerate non-agricultural
growth, and the resulting disproportionality between non-agricultural
and agricultural growth was managed by using imports financed largely
with external debt to change the structure of domestic supplies and
dampen inflation. And as Chart 2 indicates this was even more true of
the 1990s than was true in the 1980s.
A second factor allowing for growing disproportionality between agricultural
and industrial growth is a change in the pattern of demand and production,
involving a reduction in the direct agricultural-input dependence of
the non agricultural sector. As Sastry e/. al. (p. 2392) have shown,
the available input-output tables for the Indian economy indicate that:
''In 1968-69 one unit of rise in industrial output was likely to enhance
demand from agriculture by 0.247 units, which was reduced to 0.087 by
1993-94. On the other hand, in 1968-69, one unit rise in industry was
to cause 0.237 units demand from the services sector, which increased
to 0.457 units in 1993-94.'' (Table 2).
This
reduction in agricultural input dependence of the non-agricultural sector
would be greater once we take account of the growing share of service
in non-agricultural GDP. While services accounted for 43 and 48 per
cent respectively on the increment of GDP at current prices in the 1970s
and 1980s, the figure rose to 58 per cent and 62 per cent respectively
during the 1990s and the years 2000-01 to 2004-05. Given the much lower
agricultural input dependence of services, this would have strengthened
the tendency noted above.
Table
2 : Sectoral Demand Matrices Reflecting Demand Linkages |
|
Agriculture
|
Industry
|
Services |
1968-69
|
|
|
|
Agriculture |
1.23
|
0.247
|
0.059
|
Industry
|
0.087
|
1.562
|
0.230
|
Services |
0.035
|
0.237
|
1.141
|
1979-80
|
|
|
|
Agriculture |
1.214
|
0.260
|
0.083
|
Industry |
0.135
|
1.601 |
0.191
|
Services |
0.049
|
0.269
|
1.139
|
1989-90
|
|
|
|
Agriculture |
1.22
|
0.104
|
0.074
|
Industry |
0.319
|
1.729
|
0.378
|
Services |
0.144
|
0.404
|
1.318
|
1993-94
|
|
|
|
Agriculture |
1.187
|
0.087
|
0.066
|
Industry |
0.297
|
1.704
|
0.330
|
Services |
0.149
|
0.457
|
1.334
|
Source:
Sastry, D.V.S., Balwant Singh, Kaushik Bhattacharya and N.K. Unnikrishnan,
|
Sectoral
Linkages and Growth Prospects: Reflections on the Indian Economy",
|
Economic
and Political Weekly, June 14 2003
|
Thirdly,
growth in both the agricultural and non-agricultural sectors has been
such that the employment elasticity of output growth has been falling
over time. This means that employment growth has been increasingly short
of economic growth and output per worker has risen significantly in
the non-agricultural sector where output growth has been particularly
high. While a part of this rise in output per worker may have meant
an increase in the wages of sections of the already employed, it would
principally mean an increase in income inequality because of an increase
in managerial salaries and profits. Both these tendencies imply that
the indirect demand for agricultural wages goods would grow at a much
lower rate than output partly because of the slower growth in employment
and partly because increases in per capita incomes accrue to those whose
demand for food is satiated.
What is more, an ongoing study by Abhijit Sen based on recent NSS suggests
that even among the relatively poor the share of income allotted to
food consumption is being squeezed by the growing requirements set by
expenditures on health, fuel, transportation and education. The collapse
of public provision in some of these areas, requiring purchases from
private suppliers, and the increase in prices in others, is responsible
for the enforced shift away from food consumption in the household budget.
The net result of all this is that agriculture is increasingly faced
with a growing demand constraint at a time when input costs are rising.
This is a reversal of the situation prevalent till the 1980s when the
agricultural supply constraint constituted a barrier to rapid non-agricultural
growth. As a result, as Chart 3 indicates, the input-output price parity
in agriculture, which moved in favour of agricultural producers during
the 1980s, has stagnated and moved against agricultural production during
the liberalisation years since the early 1990s.
The consequence of these recent trends is that the Indian economy can
record the observed creditable rates of growth of aggregate GDP even
when the agricultural sector languishes. A feature of the growth process
in a more open and liberalised environment is that the peasantry has
a much smaller a role in sustaining economic growth and can thus be
partially excluded from development. This is partly reflected in the
fact that agriculture accounted for just 21 per cent of GDP in 2004-05.
But neither the peasantry nor the landless labourers dependent on agriculture
shrink as fast, given the pattern of agriculture growth. Employment
in the agricultural sector amounted to as much as 60 per cent in 1999-2000,
a decline of just 16 percentage points since 1950-51. It bears emphasising
that these outcomes of the patterns of growth underlie the agricultural
crisis and agrarian distress being reported from different parts of
the country, at a time when the non-agricultural economy is on a roll
and GDP is rising rapidly.