Finance
Commission reports are typically all about the devolution of resources.
The statutory job of the Finance Commissions is usually twofold: to
determine the principles for the distribution of the net proceeds of
shared tax revenues between the Centre and the States; and to provide
for revenue deficit grants from the Centre to those States whose normative
expenditures are likely to exceed normative revenue. However, more recently,
the Central Government has taken it upon itself to extend the terms
of reference of Finance Commissions to cover issues of fiscal sustainability.
Thus,
the terms of reference of the TFC include the following: ''The Commission
shall review the state of finances of the Union and the States and suggest
a plan by which the Governments, collectively and severally, may bring
about a restructuring of the public finances restoring budgetary balance,
achieving macro-economic stability and debt reduction along with equitable
growth.''
The issue of public debt has become a crucial one primarily for the
States in India. It is widely recognized that the large overhang of
debt of almost all state governments has implied such large interest
payments that the States are effectively crippled with respect to the
ability to undertake important socially necessary expenditure. Since
the States are dominantly responsible for most of the types of public
expenditure which affect the day-to-day life of the people, ranging
from law and order and basic infrastructure to health, sanitation and
education, the fiscal crisis of the States has meant that these expenditures
have been very adversely affected in most parts of India.
The need to restructure the debt of the States has been widely accepted,
for several reasons. The first is the adverse impact on expenditure
noted above. The second is the fact that for some years now, the States
have been paying higher interest rates for a variety of reasons discussed
below. The rules imposed by the Reserve Bank of India, which require
case by case permission to States for accessing commercial debt in they
are running revenue deficits, have also operated to make borrowing difficult
and have driven several States to high-conditionality debt from multilateral
agencies such as the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank.
The actual patterns of fiscal imbalances across Centre and States are
worth noting as background. Chart 1 describes the fiscal indicators
of the States since the late 1980s. It is evident that in the aggregate,
the fiscal deficit of the States as share of GDP was well within sustainable
limits, at around 3 per cent of GDP, until 1997-98. Thereafter there
was a sharp rise, led almost entirely by the rise in revenue deficit,
and this can be traced to Central government measures such as the Pay
Commission hikes.
However, since the turn of the decade, the States' revenue deficit as
a share of GDP has been rising even though they have cut spending and
improved revenue effort. The primary revenue balance has been in surplus,
sometimes quite sharply so, even as the revenue and fiscal deficits
have been increasing, largely because of the effect of the debt overhang
and the unduly high interest rates the States have had to pay.
This
has been further compounded by the decline in central transfers to States
over the years. Such transfers have declined from 40 per cent of the
central tax receipts in the first half of the 1990s to an average of
36 per cent after 1996. Since the Centre's tax revenues have declined
as a share of GDP over this period, this has meant an even sharper decline
as a per cent of GDP. In fact, the States' tax effort has been significantly
better than that of the Centre. So the apparent ''lack of fiscal correction''
by the States in recent years relates entirely to the debt structure
and its implications.
Contrast this with the performance of the Centre, as indicated in Chart
2. While the fiscal deficit declined in the early 1990s, it rose again
quite sharply in 1994-95, after financial liberalisation measures raised
the cost of borrowing by the government and led to increased interest
payments. The subsequent rise in fiscal deficit ratios, post-1997, has
not been only because of interest payments, however, but because of
other expenditures essentially on the revenue account and declining
tax ratios, as revenue deficits and the primary deficits have increased
as share of GDP.
As
Chart 3 shows, the total debt of the States was more or less constant
as a share of GDP for around a decade until 1997-98, and so was the
ratio of debt to total revenue receipts. Thereafter, however, states'
debt as a proportion of GDP has ballooned and the ratio of debt to revenue
receipts of states has nearly doubled. This is clearly an unsustainable
situation, but, as noted earlier, it has not been brought about either
by worsening tax generation (which has been broadly stable) or excessive
total expenditure, since the primary balance (net of interest payments)
generally been in surplus except for only a few years. Rather, this
is due to the combination of falling central transfers and related inability
to repay the high interest on previously contracted debt.
There
are various indicators of debt sustainability which are typically estimated,
but it is generally accepted that at the very minimum, the growth of
nominal GDP must be greater than or at least equal to the rate of growth
of interest that has to be paid. It is evident from Chart 4 that until
1997-98, such a condition was more than adequately met. However, since
then, not only has the rate of growth of nominal GDP fallen, but interest
rates have remained consistently high. As a result, for three critical
years since 2000, this condition has not been met, which obviously makes
servicing the debt difficult if not impossible. It is this which has
then led to further debt accumulation, which obviously makes the trajectory
an unsustainable one.
But
why have interest rates remained so high if the general perception of
declining interest rates is valid? This is where the discriminatory
attitude of the Centre towards States in general has had such a negative
impact. Under the Constitution, the Centre has the power to determine
both the extent and the terms of borrowing by the States from all sources,
not only from itself. This power has been used increasingly by the Centre
to restrict States from accessing different types of loans and in effect
dramatically increasing the cost of borrowing for States.
There are several ways in which this has been done. The central government
has been charging the state governments higher rates of interest on
debt which it issues to them, in fact substantially higher than the
Centre has been paying itself. The Centre has also used aggressively
its Constitutional powers to limit the ability of the States to borrow
from the market and from commercial banks. Any state government which
has a revenue deficit therefore has to seek special permission from
the Reserve Bank of India to borrow from commercial banks, permission
which is not necessarily granted. Finally, state governments taking
on debt provided by multilateral institutions or even loans from bilateral
donors have not paid the rate of interest charged by them, but a much
higher rate imposed by the Centre, which is the intermediary for such
transactions.
The
consequence of all this is evident in Chart 5, which gives some indication
of the average rates of interest paid on debt contracted by the Centre
and the States. This gives the average, not marginal, rates, but the
shapes of the curves provide an indication of the marginal changes.
From around 1997 onwards, the average rate of interest paid by the Centre
on its own debt has fallen significantly, from 9 per cent to around
6.5 per cent, which suggests a much sharper decline at the margin. By
contrast, the average interest rate paid by the States has remained
broadly stable over this entire period, so marginal rates have not really
come down for them. So the Centre has effectively been reaping usurious
benefits from its lending to state governments, and these have amounted
in recent periods to around 1 per cent of GDP, or around 20 per cent
of the central fiscal deficit.
This is the context in which the TFC's discussion of states' debt restructuring
has to be analysed. The TFC has indeed suggested a formula for reducing
the burden of debt of the states, and also for reducing the interest
rates payable by them. However, the positive effects of such a proposal
have been drastically undermined by the proposed condition sought to
be imposed by the TFC, of forcing states to enact fiscal responsibility
legislation and holding to arbitrary targets for fiscal indicators,
in order to get the benefits of dent reduction.
We will provide a discussion of the debt restructuring package and critically
assess the possible effects of such conditions upon state finances in
the next issue of MacroScan.