Clearly,
we are back in another phase of sharply rising global food prices, which
is wreaking further devastation on populations in developing countries
that have already been ravaged by several years of rising prices and
falling employment chances. The food
price index of the FAO in December 2010 surpassed
its previous peak of June 2008, the month that is still thought of as
the extreme peak of the world food crisis.
Some of the biggest increases have come in the prices of sugar and edible
oils. But even staple prices have shown sharp increases, with the biggest
increase in wheat prices, which doubled in the second half of 2010 and
have been increasing since then. Rice prices have been relatively stable
in global trade over the past year in comparison, but are still much
higher (by around 48 per cent) than they were at the start of 2008.
Of course this need not (and should not) translate directly into prices
faced by consumers in poor developing countries. Certainly, given the
much lower per capita incomes in such countries and therefore lower
purchasing power of the people, it should be expected that there would
be some public mediation of the relationship between global prices and
domestic food prices. This is all the more desirable, if not essential,
in periods of high price volatility in global trade, such as has been
observed in the past four years. Otherwise, poor consumers in the developing
world for whom basic food grains still accounts for around 40-50 per
cent of the consumption basket, would be sharply affected by such price
movements.
As it happens, the period of dramatic increases in price volatility
in global markets has also been one in which there has been very high
transmission of international price changes to domestic prices in many
developing countries. This is evident from a quick perusal of retail
price changes in wheat and rice markets in some developing countries.
Consider India, a country which currently has the largest number of
hungry people in the world and very poor nutrition indicators in general,
despite nearly two decades of rapid income growth. Chart 1 shows the
behaviour of retail wheat prices in two major cities – Delhi and Mumbai
– in relation to the global trade price of wheat (relating to US wheat
in the Chicago Board of Trade).
Two
important features are immediately evident from this chart. First, the
substantial variation in retail prices across the two Indian cities
(which would be reinforced by other data showing the variation in retail
prices across other towns and cities), which suggests that there is
still absence of a national market for essential food items, even those
that can be transported and stored easily. Second, the degree to which
price changes, have tracked international prices.
Many analysts have argued that the Indian food grain market is insulated
from the international market because of the system of domestic public
food procurement and distribution. Indeed, until the early part of the
last decade, this has been generally true. However, the opening of agricultural
items to international trade without quantitative restrictions has clearly
allowed for greater impact of global prices on domestic prices.
Further, the public distribution system itself has been increasingly
run down in the past two decades. Recently, this has been further complicated
by the insistence of the central government on raising procurement prices
and procuring more, but not distributing the increased procurement to
states to allow them to provide wheat to the defined “non-poor” population
in a manner that would restrain prices. Instead, the focus has been
on building central stocks, which has even turned out to be somewhat
counterproductive because of the lack of adequate storage facilities.
As a result, Indian retail wheat prices have been higher than global
prices in both these urban centres. They rose by about 30 per cent in
the year to October 2010 as global prices also increased.
Chart 2 describes the behaviour of wheat retail prices in two other
South Asian countries – one a domestic producer and occasional exporter
of wheat (Pakistan) and the other an importer in which wheat is still
important in fulfilling dietary needs (Bangladesh).
Bangaldeshi
retail prices have closely tracked global trade prices, always remaining
higher. This in itself is significant given the low purchasing power
of most Bangaldeshi consumers. It indicates that there is little to
no mediation between import prices and prices faced by consumers in
Bangaldesh, and that the latter are subject to the fierce fluctuations
and rising tendencies that have characterised the global market.
What is surprising is that the same is broadly true of Pakistan (the
retail price here relates to Lahore city). What is of interest in this
case is that while periods of rising prices appear to be marked by rapid
transmission to Lahore retail prices, the period of global price reduction
shows no such tendency. In fact, Lahore retail prices kept rising even
as global prices came down, such that even after the latest global price
surge, global prices are still at around the same level as the Pakistan
retail price.
The food grain commodity that is the most important for most Asian consumers
is rice, which remains the grain that is dominantly consumed by large
parts of the population in most of the region. Chart 3 indicates the
behaviour of rice prices in Sri Lanka and the Philippines, in relation
to the global price.
Note
that the two are rather diffferent countries: while Sri Lanka exports
cash crops, it is close to self-sufficient in rice in recent times,
thanks to major efforts to promote domestic rice cultivation. Rice is
of course by far the dominant food crop, accounting for around 60 per
cent of dietary requirements. The Philippines, on the other hand, is
a rice producer but also depends on imports for between 15 and 20 per
cent of domestic consumption, so it is likely to be far more affected
by international prices. Rice accounts for around 46 per cent of dietary
requirements.
Retail rice prices in Sri Lanka (referring to Colombo in this chart)
very closely track international prices. Other than the extreme peak
of June 2008, retail prices have been close to global trade prices,
despite the lack of reliance on imports. So the global price volatility
has been reflected even in a country that is largely self-sufficient
in rice. In the Philippines, the story is even more worrying. Rice prices
(referring here to retail prices in Metro Manila) rose dramatically
in response to global price movements, almost to the same level as the
peak in June 2008; came down as global prices fell in the second half
of 2008, but since then have actually been higher in the Philippines
than in international trade. Further they have continued to rise even
as rice prices have stabilised in the global market.
Chart 4 describes retail price movements in India (Delhi) and Bangladesh
(national average). It is worth remembering the retail prices vary quite
significantly across towns and cities in India; even so this provides
an important indication of recent patterns.
According
to FAO data, India is completely self-sufficient in rice whereas Bangladesh
currently is only 97 per cent sufficient, importing around 3 per cent
of its requirement (possibly more if the cross-border smuggling is taken
into account). While retail rice prices did not peak in June 2008, they
have risen steadily in India and increased by around 26 per cent in
the second half of 2010 alone. In Bangladesh there has been much greater
volatility, with prices rising sharply following the global surge in
2007-08, then falling and then rising again. In the past two years retail
rice prices in Bangladesh have increased by more than 35 per cent.
These trends in different Asian countries point to a broader trend whereby
prices in domestic food markets are more and more strongly affected
by and related to international price changes. This is a matter of some
concern, especially in the context of the ongoing extreme volatility
in global prices.
The recent price increases, just as those in 2007-08 (which were followed
by declines) do not represent significant changes in global demand and
supply balances. Rather, once again, it is likely that a combination
of panic buying and speculative financial activity is playing a role
in driving world food prices up well beyond anything that is warranted
by real quantity movements. The most recent data on financial activity
in commodity futures markets from the US Commodity Future Trading Commission
suggest that until the end of January the net long positions of index
investors had increased dramatically in commodities like wheat and corn.
This is likely to have increased even more in the past few weeks, given
the announcements about lower levels of public stocks.
Once again we are also seeing contango in these commodity markets, with
futures prices higher than spot prices. This is all a repeat of 2007
and the first half of 2008, when prices of these commodities nearly
tripled. And it is not surprising, because the regulations that could
prevent or at least limit such speculative financial activity are not
yet in place, and there are even concerns about whether they will be
effective or toothless in the implementation.
We now have direct recent experience of how financial speculation in
commodity markets can create not only unprecedented volatility, but
also affect prices in developing countries with extreme effects on hunger
and nutrition for at least half of humanity. The case for moving swiftly
to ensure effective regulation in this area – and for dealing with supply
issues in a serious and sustainable way - has never been more compelling.