After
having failed to salvage a crisis-afflicted banking system by guaranteeing
deposits, providing refinance against toxic assets and pumping in preference
capital, governments in the US, UK, Ireland and elsewhere are being
forced to nationalize their leading banks by buying into new equity
shares. What is more, even staunch free market advocates like former
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan, who made the case for regulatory
forbearance and oversaw a regime of easy money that fueled the speculative
bubble (which he declared was just ''froth''), now see nationalization
as inevitable. In an interview to the Financial Times, Greenspan, identified
by the newspaper ''as the high priest of laisser-faire capitalism'',
said: "It may be necessary to temporarily nationalise some banks
in order to facilitate a swift and orderly restructuring. I understand
that once in a hundred years this is what you do."
This ideological leap has come at the end of a long transition during
which the understanding of the nature of the problem afflicting the
banks in these countries has been through many changes. Initially, when
the subprime crisis broke, this was seen as confined to subprime markets
and to institutions holding mortgage-backed securities. Since banks
were seen as entities which had either stayed out of these markets or
had transferred the risks associated with subprime mortgage loans by
securitizing them and selling them on to others, the banking system,
the core of the financial sector, was seen as relatively free of the
disease.
In practice, however, the exposure of banks to these mortgage-backed
securities and collateralized debt obligations was by no means small.
Because they wanted to partake of the anticipated high returns or because
they were carrying an inventory of such assets that were yet to be marketed,
banks had a significant holding of these assets when the crisis broke.
A number of banks had also set up special purpose vehicles for creating
and distributing such assets which too were holders of what turned out
to be toxic securities. And finally banks had lent to institutions that
had leveraged small volumes of equity to make huge investments in these
kinds of assets. In the event, the banking system was indeed directly
or indirectly exposed to these assets in substantial measure.
It needs noting that even if the exposure of banks to these assets was
a small proportion of the total amount in circulation, the effect of
such assets turning worthless can be debilitating for the banks for
two reasons. First, even if the proportion of derivative assets held
by the banks was small, the value of that exposure tended to be high
because of the large volume of such assets circulating in the system.
Because securitization is geared to transferring risk off the balance
sheet of the originator of the base asset, the tendency in the system
is for the creators of such assets to discount risk and create large
volumes of excessively risky credit assets, as happened in the subprime
mortgage market. The effects of this tendency to sharply increase the
volume of asset-based securities was aggravated by the easy money environment
that was created by the Federal Reserve under Greenspan as part of an
effort to keep a credit-financed boom going in the system.
Second, the equity base of most banks is relatively small even when
they follow Basel norms with regard to capital adequacy. Banks can use
a variety of assets to ensure such adequacy and the required volume
of regulatory capital can be reduced by obtaining assets with high ratings
(which we now know are not an adequate indicator of risk). This results
in the available regulatory capital being small relative to the risky
asset-backed securities held by the banks.
The difficulty with these kinds of bad assets is that they are valued
on marked-to-market principles, implying that since these assets are
not all being traded, there is a lag in the recognition of the losses
suffered through holding such assets. In the US, the process of price
discovery began a long time back when in August 2007 Bear Stearns declared
that investments in one of its hedge funds set up to invest in mortgage
backed securities had lost all its value and those in a second such
fund were valued at nine cents for every dollar of original investment.
What was noteworthy was that Bear Stearns was a highly leveraged institution
holding assets valued at $395.4 billion in November 2007 on an equity
base of just $11.8 billion. Thus it was not just that the assets held
by the bank were bad, but that there were many other institutions, including
banks, that were exposed to bad assets through their relationship with
Stearns. Yet they were slow in recognizing their potential losses.
On March 14, 2008, Bear Stearns was put on life support with what appeared
to be an unlimited loan facility for 28 days delivered through Wall
Street Bank J.P. Morgan Chase. That life support came when it became
clear that, faced with a liquidity crunch, Bear Stearns would have to
unwind its assets by selling them at prices that would imply huge losses.
This would have had spin off effects on other financial firms since
the investment bank had multiple points of interaction with the rest
of the financial community. Besides being a counter party to a range
of transactions that would turn questionable, its efforts to liquidate
its assets would affect other investors holding the same or related
securities and derivatives through a price decline. Fearing that the
ripple effects would lead to a systemic collapse, the Fed, in collaboration
with JP Morgan, sought to prop up the investment bank. The Financial
Times quoted an unnamed official who reportedly declared that Bear Stearns
was too ''interconnected'' to be allowed to fail at a time when financial
markets were extremely fragile.
However, this lesson had not been learnt in full. When in September
last year, troubled Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc., the fourth largest
investment bank on Wall Street came to the table with requests for support,
it was refused the same. The refusal of the state to take over the responsibility
of managing failing firms was supposed to send out a strong message.
Not only was Lehman forced to file for bankruptcy, but a giant like
Merrill Lynch that had also notched up large losses due to sub-prime
related exposures decided that it should sort matters out before there
were no suitors interested in salvaging its position as well. In a surprise
move, Bank of America that was being spoken to as a potential buyer
of Lehman was persuaded to acquire Merrill Lynch instead, bringing down
two of the major independent investment banks on Wall Street.
This was, however, only part of the problem that Lehman left behind.
The other major issue was the impact its bankruptcy would have on its
creditors. Citigroup and Bank of New York Mellon were estimated to have
an exposure to the institution that was placed at upwards of a staggering
$155 billion. A clutch of Japanese banks, led by Aozora Bank, were owed
an amount in excess of a billion. There were European banks that had
significant exposure. And all of these were already faced with strained
balance sheets. Soon trouble broke in banking markets with a spurt of
bank failures seeming inevitable. Though indications of this problem
emerged at least a year-and-a-half ago, what was surprising was that
the full import of the problem at hand was not recognized. In the US,
and elsewhere in the world, the problem confronting the banks was seen
as two-fold: ensuring adequate access to liquidity so that they are
not victims of a run; and, cleaning up their balance sheets by writing
off or getting rid of their bad assets.
In what followed, central banks pumped huge amounts of liquidity into
the system and reduced interest rates. In the US, the Federal Reserve
offered to hold the worthless paper that the banks had accumulated and
provide them credit at low interest rates in return. But the problem
would not go away. By then every institution suspected that every other
institution was insolvent and did not want to risk lending. The money
was there but credit would not flow through the pipe with damaging consequences
for the financial system and for the real economy.
It was at this point that it was realised that what needed to be done
was to clear out the bad assets with the banks. Among the smart ideas
thought up for the purpose was the notion of splitting the system into
‘good' and ‘bad' banks. If a set of bad banks could be set up with public
money, and these banks acquired the bad assets of the banks, the balance
sheets of the latter, it was argued, will be repaired. The bad banks
themselves can serve as asset reconstruction corporations that might
be able to sell off a part of their bad assets as the good banks get
about their business and the economy revives.
This idea missed the whole point, because it did not take account of
the price at which the bad assets were to be acquired. If they were
acquired at par or more, it would amount to blowing taxpayers' money
to save badly behaved bank managers, since the assets were likely to
be worth a fraction of what they were actually bought for. On the other
hand, if some scheme such as a reverse auction (or one in which sellers
bid down prices to entice the buyer to acquire their assets) is used
to dispose of the bad assets, then the prices of these assets would
be extremely low and good banks would incur huge losses which they would
have to write down leading to insolvency. The only way out it appeared
was if these banks just wrote down their assets and were saved from
bankruptcy by the government through recapitalisation or the injection
of equity capital into them. Additional equity injection leading to
nationalization seemed unavoidable. What is more as the dimensions of
the problem needing resolution became clear the extent of the nationalization
required seems substantial.
In its update to the Global Financial Stability Report for 2008, issued
on January 28, 2009, the IMF has estimated the losses incurred by US
and European banks from bad assets that originated in the US at $2.2
trillion. Barely 2 months back it had placed the figure at $1.4 trillion.
Loss estimates seem to be galloping and we are still counting. The IMF
estimates that these banks that have already obtained much support including
capital would need further new capital infusions of around half a trillion.
With that much and perhaps more capital going in, public ownership of
banking would be near total in some countries. By late January 2006,
Bloomberg estimates, banks had written down $792 billion in losses and
raised $826 billion in capital, of which $380 billion came from governments.
Though
the problem originated in the US, nationalization occurred first in
Iceland (where the need was immediate), in Ireland starting with Anglo
Irish Bank and expected to be necessary in the case of Bank of Ireland
and Allied Irish Banks and in the UK were Royal Bank of Scotland and
Lloyds Group are now under dominant public control, and others are expected
to follow. However, even here the willingness to declare the process
as nationalization is still lacking. In the US, the government initially
found ways of providing capital but not demanding a say. But this proved
disastrous, since it became clear that old habits of managers used to
being paid to speculate die hard. Huge salaries and bonuses were being
paid out of money meant to save dying banks. So intervention became
necessary and is part of the plank being espoused by President Barack
Obama. Yet, when the threat of inevitable nationalization resulted in
a sharp fall in the share values of the likes of Bank of America and
Citigroup, that are surviving on government money, White House spokesman
Rober Gibbs told reporters that ''The President (Barack Obama) believes
that a privately held banking system regulated by the government'' is
what the US should have.
What is missed is that the inevitability of public ownership that is
now being recognized stems from a deeper source. The problems that drove
the system to inevitable nationalization arose because of the transition
in banking from a structure that was based on a ''buy-and-hold'' strategy
(where credit assets were created and held to maturity) to one that
relied on a ''originate-and-sell'' strategy in which credit risk was
transferred through a layered process of securitisation that created
the so-called toxic assets. The deregulation of banking was crucial
for this transition. It permitted securitisation and also allowed a
geographically extensive banking system to create credit assets far
in excess of what would have been the case in a more regulated system,
so that they could be packaged and sold. The role of banks as mere agents
for generating the credit assets that could be packaged into products
meant that risk was discounted at the point of origination, since banks
felt that they were not holding the risks even while they were earning
commissions and fees. This transition was made possible by the process
of deregulation that began in the 1980s and culminated in the Gramm-Leach-Bliley
Modernization of Act of 1999, which completely dismantled the regulatory
structure and the restrictions on cross-sector activity put in place
by Glass-Steagall in the 1930s.
Why did deregulation occur, when a system regulated by Glass-Steagall
and all it represented served the US well during the Golden Age of high
growth in the US? It did because implicit in the regulatory structure
epitomised by Glass -Steagall was the notion that banks would earn a
relatively small rate of return defined largely by the net interest
margin, or the difference between deposit and lending rates adjusted
for intermediation costs. Thus, in 1986 in the US, the reported return
on assets for all commercial banks with assets of $500 million or more
averaged about 0.7 per cent, with the average even for high-performance
banks amounting to merely 1.4 per cent. This outcome of the regulatory
structure was, however, in conflict with the fact that these banks were
privately owned. What Glass-Steagall was saying was that because the
role of the banks was so important for capitalism they had to be regulated
in a fashion where even though they were privately owned they would
earn less profit than other institutions in the financial sector and
private institutions outside the financial sector. This amounted to
a deep inner contradiction in the system which set up pressures for
deregulation. Those pressure gained strength during the inflationary
years in the 1970s when tight monetary policies pushed up interest rates
elsewhere but not in the banks. The result was a flight of depositors
and a threat to the viability of banking which was used to win the deregulation
that gradually paved the way for the problems of today. What became
clear was that Glass-Steagall type of regulation of a privately owned
banking system was internally contradictory. It would inevitably lead
to deregulation. But as we know now such deregulation seems to inevitably
lead back to nationalisation. So what capitalism needs for its proper
functioning is a publicly owned banking system. That implies that the
current move to ''inevitable'' nationalisation cannot be just ''temporary''
as Greenspan wants it to be.