The
major positive feature of the recently announced fiscal measures is the
evidence of increased central government tax revenues (Chart 1) and an
increase in the tax-GDP ratio. For the Centre, the gross tax-GDP ratio,
after rising from 9.2 per cent in 2003-04 to 9.8 per cent in 2004-05,
has increased further to 10.5 per cent in 2005-06 (RE), and is estimated
to increase to 11.2 per cent in 2006-07.
Coming
after more than fifteen years of decline, this is clearly a positive sign.
It is even more noteworthy because, as part of the process of import liberalisation,
the government has been reducing peak and weighted-average import tariffs.
If the Budget Speech 2006-07 is to be believed, this has happened because
there has been a structural shift in the central government's ability
to mobilise resources. According to the Finance Minister: ''the strategy
of enhanced revenue mobilisation through reasonable rates, better compliance
and widening of the tax base is yielding tangible results.''
Mr. Chidambaram has identified three sources for this tax buoyancy: a
regime of reasonable rates of taxation, improved tax administration and
a widening of the tax base. The first of these, reflecting the view that
moderate tax rates make people more willing to pay taxes resulting in
improved tax buoyancy, is a mere statement of belief with no logical basis.
It underlies the infamous ''Laffer curve'' argument, which has been shown
to be empirically unjustified in many contexts. Further, while tax administration
may have improved, persisting arrears indicate that this has not gone
far enough. It cannot be an explanation for the kind of buoyancy that
has been recorded.
To assess which factors are adequate explanations of tax buoyancy and
gauge their relative roles, it is best to turn to the available evidence.
Between 2004-05 and 2005-06, the gross tax revenues of the Centre rose
by a little more than Rs.65,000 crore or by 21.4 per cent. With real (inflation
adjusted) growth in GDP placed at around 7.5 per cent in that year and
prices having risen by 4-5 per cent, this increase in tax collections
is well above the increase in nominal GDP.
But not all the principal sources of revenue have been characterised by
such buoyancy. A breakdown of the increase (Chart 2) indicates that close
to a third of this increase was on account of corporation taxes, which
rose by 25.3 per cent, a little more than a quarter was on account of
income taxes (characterised by a 26 per cent rise) and around a fifth
on account of excise duties (20 per cent). Increases in other significant
taxes such as the service tax (13.5 per cent) and customs duties (10.1
per cent) were more or less in line with the increase in GDP.
The relative lack of buoyancy of the service tax is surprising, since
a feature of Indian economic growth during the 1990s has been a much faster
growth in services as compared with the commodity producing sectors like
agriculture and manufacturing. Recognising that the coverage is not enough,
or that the net has not been widened enough, the Finance Minister has
made an effort, however limited, to extend the reach of the service tax.
The relatively poor performance on the customs duties front is also intriguing
for two reasons. To start with, the high and rising level of oil prices
should have helped mobilise additional revenues from these taxes. Further,
non-oil imports have been buoyant, because of the rise in GDP. If despite
these developments customs duty collections have failed to keep pace with
GDP, the lesson to take home is that tariff reductions associated with
trade liberalisation have diluted the role of customs duties as a revenue-generating
device.
Thus, if the buoyancy in tax revenues has to be explained we have to understand
why, despite moderate tax rates, increases in corporation and income taxes
in particular, and excise duties to a lesser extent, have been larger
than warranted by the increase in aggregate GDP. In the circumstance,
there appears to be only one explanation. Growing inequality in the distribution
of income between the corporate and non-corporate sectors and between
richer and poorer individuals has shifted income in favour of the higher
tax bracket. If this is occurring, even for a given level of compliance,
tax revenues from these sources should rise faster than aggregate GDP.
One indication that this could have played a role comes from recent evidence
on corporate profitability. The net profit of the top 20 companies according
to market capitalisation included in the Economic Times 500 rose by a
dizzying 46.5 per cent during the four quarters ending September 2005
when compared with the corresponding period of the previous year. This
trend has since continued. This would make the buoyancy in corporation
taxes woefully inadequate relative to profit movements.
This trend in corporate India has been accompanied by a similar movement
in corporate and private sector salaries resulting in substantial increases
in inter-personal income inequalities. It is this which appears to have
delivered more taxes than warranted by the trend in aggregate GDP, but
perhaps still not enough.
What this means is that if this increase in tax-GDP ratio is to mark a
real turning point and be sustained into the future, it will be essential
to tax the rich more, for example by reinstating capital gains tax. |
Box
1. Capital Gains Tax
Just
before the FII surge began, and influenced perhaps by the sharp
fall in net FII investments in 2002-03, the then Finance Minister
declared in the Budget for 2003-04: ''In order to give a further
fillip to the capital markets, it is now proposed to exempt all
listed equities that are acquired on or after March 1, 2003, and
sold after the lapse of a year, or more, from the incidence of
capital gains tax. Long term capital gains tax will, therefore,
not hereafter apply to such transactions. This proposal should
facilitate investment in equities.'' (Ministry of Finance, Government
of India 2002: Paragraph 46).
In the very next year, the Finance Minister of the UPA government
endorsed this move. In his 2004 budget speech he announced his
decision to ''abolish the tax on long-term capital gains from
securities transactions altogether.'' (Ministry of Finance, Government
of India 2004: Paragraph 111). It is no doubt true that he attempted
to introduce a securities transactions tax of 0.15 per cent to
partially neutralise any loss in revenues. But a post-budget downturn
in the market forced him to reduce the extent of this tax and
curtail its coverage, resulting in a substantial loss in revenue.
Thus, an extravagant fiscal concession appears to have triggered
the speculative surge in stock markets that still persists.
The implications of this extravagance can be assessed with a simple
calculation which, even while unsatisfactory, is illustrative.
Let us consider 28 of the 30 Sensex companies for which uniform
data on daily share prices and trading volumes are available for
the years 2004 and 2005 from the Prowess Database of the Centre
for Monitoring the Indian Economy. (In one case (Larsen &
Toubro), data on trading volumes were not available in Prowess
for 25 out of 254 trading days in 2004). For those days, we use
the annual average trading volume as a proxy.)
Long term capital gains were defined for taxation purposes as
gains made on those assets held by the purchaser for at least
365 days. These gains were earlier being taxed at the rate of
10 per cent.
Assume now that all shares of these 28 Sensex companies bought
on each trading day in 2004 were sold after 366 days or the immediately
following trading day in 2005. Multiplying the increase in prices
of the shares concerned over these 366 days by the assumed number
of shares sold for each day in 2005, we estimate the total capital
gains that could have been garnered in 2005 at Rs. 78,569 crore.
If these gains had been taxed at the rate of 10 per cent prevalent
earlier, the revenue yielded would have amounted to Rs. 7,857.
That reflects the revenue foregone by the state and the benefit
accruing to the buyers of these shares. It is true that not all
shares of these companies bought in 2004 would have been sold
a year-and-one-day later. But some shares which were purchased
prior to 2004 would have been sold during 2005, presumably with
a bigger margin of gain. And this estimate relates to just 28
companies.
In practice, therefore the estimate provided is likely to be an
underestimate of the total capital gains from transactions that
would have been subject to the capital gains tax. While it needs
to be noted that the surge in the market may not have occurred
if India had not been made a capital gains tax haven, the figure
does reflect the kind of gains accruing to financial investors
in the wake of the surge. Once the FII increase resulting from
these factors triggered a boom in stock prices, expectations of
further price increases took over, and the incentive to benefit
from untaxed capital gains was only strengthened.
|
|